ABBY L. GILBERT
Thomas Ewing, Sr.: Ohio's Advocate
for a National Bank
Thomas Ewing, Sr., lawyer, Ohio Senator,
and Cabinet officer who asserted "we
must have a National Bank," and
Abbott Lawrence, Massachusetts industrialist,
politician, statesman, and
philanthropist who firmly believed "the currency of this
wide extended country never could be
properly regulated without some great central
controlling power over the State
banks," were very influential in the attempt to
charter a third national bank in 1841.1
The Whigs advocated a bank. From their
point of view Andrew Jackson's veto of
the rechartering of the Second Bank of the
United States in 1832 had not settled
the issue. Only a national bank would provide
a uniform national currency, regulate
the money supply, and provide the capital
needed for sustained economic growth.
The development of a genuinely national
economy was the goal of the Whig party.
Under Henry Clay, Daniel Webster, Thomas
Ewing, and business leaders, such as
Abbott Lawrence, the Whig party sought
to foster the growth of American capitalism
and promote economic opportunity and
prosperity through government intervention
in the economy. The Whigs had a more
realistic appreciation of the needs of a
dynamic economy than the Jacksonian
Democrats, whose policy on the national
level, and to some extent in Ohio, was
negative. They eliminated the national bank
first, and then attempted to rid the
state of banks in the belief that the destruction of
all privileges would bring economic
equality. During the 1830's and 1840's the
Democrats drifted toward the wholly
inadequate policy of hard-money, while the
Whigs, realizing the supply of specie
(coin) was insufficient to meet the demands
of economic growth, insisted upon a federal
bank and on credit supplied by local
state banks.2 Had the Whigs
succeeded, an element of centralized control would
have been established in the financial
structure of the nation's banking system, and
this control would have significantly
affected the development of American capitalism.
Thomas Ewing was born in West Liberty,
Virginia, December 28, 1789. Four
years later his family moved to Athens
County, Ohio, where he was raised on the
1. Thomas Ewing to Mr. Silliman, April
19, 1841, Box 43, Thomas Ewing Family Papers,
Manuscript Division, Library of
Congress; Congressional Globe, 24 Cong., 2 Sess., 272.
2. Glyndon G. Van Deusen, The
Jacksonian Era, 1828-1848 (New York, 1959), xv-xvi, 50,
97-98, 118-119, 263-265; Melvyn
Dubofsky, "Daniel Webster and the Whig Theory of Eco-
nomic Growth: 1828-1848," New
England Quarterly, XLII (December 1969), 551-557,
571-572.
Ms. Gilbert is an economist in the
Banking and Economic Research Department, Office of
the Comptroller of the Currency, U. S.
Treasury Department.
6 OHIO
HISTORY
frontier. Ewing worked for three years
in the Kanawha salt works in order to earn
enough to attend Ohio University. He
received the school's first bachelor's degree
in 1815. In 1816 he was admitted to the
bar and went on to become one of Ohio's
outstanding legal minds. His giant
intellect, logical thought, clear convincing argu-
ment, and incisive style made him a
lawyer of the first rank, gaining him a national
reputation as the "Logician of the
West." Also, taking an active interest in politics,
the young lawyer soon became recognized
as the most eminent Whig in Ohio. Quiet,
gentle, self-controlled, courteous,
dignified, and generous to those who differed with
him, Ewing was described by Daniel
Webster as the best informed gentleman he
ever met.3
As a businessman Thomas Ewing had a wide
range of interests. Since early man-
hood he engaged in salt manufacture,
which contributed much to the economic devel-
opment of Ohio. He owned stock in
railroads, purchased large coal lands, and dealt
heavily in land script. Realizing that
Ohio was underdeveloped and that farmers
were unable to market their produce
economically, he took a deep interest in the
building of canals and assisted in both
public and private efforts. Ewing served as
one of the nine directors and for some
time as president of the Lancaster Lateral
Canal Company, a private company created
to dig a branch to the main Ohio and
Erie canal.4
Ewing was also involved in banking. From
1818 to 1829 he was Prosecuting
Attorney of Fairfield County and
succeeded in breaking a counterfeit ring there.
By 1828 he was a member of the board of
directors and at times handled the legal
business of the Lancaster Ohio Bank,
established in 1816. He served until the
bank closed in 1842.5 From
this position Ewing was able to experience first hand
the difficulties of banking under the
prevailing nonuniform currency system, the
futility of the laws which tried to correct
the situation, and the problems of supplying
development capital for orderly economic
growth without a national bank.
In political philosophy Thomas Ewing was
a conservative Whig and opposed the
radical antibank, hard-money Democrats.
A nationalist, who recognized that the
Ohio Valley's economic interests and
lines of trade bound it to every other section
of the country, he advocated internal
improvements and a federal bank. Only a gov-
ernment with a policy of active
participation in the economic development of the
West would bring greater prosperity to
Ohio. Ewing was a strong supporter of the
protective tariff policy advocated by
Henry Clay. In August 1827 the western lawyer
had actively pursued this interest at
the Harrisburg Convention, called by advocates
of protection. He was one of Ohio's
seven delegates who helped to form the state's
position that the farmer and mechanic
were entitled to protective tariff benefits equal
to those of the merchant. The convention
sent a memorial to Congress asserting that
continued prosperity depended upon a
protective policy. Ewing met Abbott Law-
rence at the conference and a lifelong
friendship began. When the General Assembly
The major sources of specie during the
first half of the 19th century were trade, foreign
investment, and new supplies from
domestic and foreign mines. Domestic gold and silver did
not become plentiful until after the
1840's.
3. Ellen Ewing Sherman, Memorial of
Thomas Ewing of Ohio (New York, 1873), 1-30,
94-95, 100-101, 111, 119, 123-126, 179,
202, 230.
4. Paul I. Miller, "Thomas Ewing:
Last of the Whigs" (unpublished Ph.D. dissertation,
The Ohio State University, 1933), 33-35,
316; Thomas Ewing, "Oration at the Commence-
ment of the Ohio Canal at the Licking
Summit," Ohio Archaeological and Historical Quar-
terly, XXXIV (January 1925), 77-84.
5. Ewing to John McLean, April 18, 1828,
Letterbook, pp. 54-55, Box 165, Ewing Papers;
Miller, "Thomas Ewing," 16-17,
28-29, 52, 122-124.
Thomas Ewing 7
elected Thomas Ewing to the Senate in
1830, he was voted onto the most important
committee of the session, the special
committee on the application for recharter of
the Bank of the United States. There he
became friends with Clay and Webster and
renewed his friendship with Lawrence,
who was serving in the House.6
Abbott Lawrence was born December 16,
1792, to one of the leading families of
Massachusetts and made his fortune in
the firm of A. & A. Lawrence. The Law-
rences, in association with other
textile magnates, developed the cotton textile indus-
try in New England at a time when most
United States merchants looked with indif-
ference if not distrust at domestic attempts
to compete with the fabrics of Europe.
The industrialist realized the
importance of diversification and urged the West to
develop. Lawrence early saw the products
of the West and South enjoying a home
market and advocated a national bank,
protective tariff, and railroads to achieve a
truly national economy. In March 1833 he
wrote Henry Clay that if internal im-
provements continued there was no doubt
that "this Union would be bound by ties
stronger than all the constitutions that
human wisdom could devise." Liberal minded
and farsighted, a man of honor,
integrity, intuitive insight, and business sagacity,
Abbott Lawrence became the most
important man in the Boston community.
Since Lawrence recognized the value of
uniform currency, he and other Boston
entrepreneurs established the Suffolk
Bank System, a great clearing system for
redeeming bank notes which put New
England's currency on a sound basis. By
rigidly controlling the extension of
credit, the Suffolk Bank was able to suppress
speculative local banking. Because of
this stability, state bank notes achieved so
wide a circulation in Massachusetts that
the Bank of the United States, as a note
issuing institution, was not important.
In 1823, five years after the Suffolk Bank was
founded, the circulation of the United
States Bank was 5.5 percent of the total; a
decade later the ratio stood at
$7,889,110 to $264,720, roughly 3 percent, the lowest
ratio in any of the states. Nor was the
Bank important as a source of capital.7
By contrast, the Bank of the United
States became a powerful force in the devel-
opment and prosperity of Ohio and the
West. The Ohio General Assembly char-
tered twenty banks in 1816-1818, more
than all the northwestern states combined.
Power of note issue was unrestricted and
the state was flooded with varied and often
unredeemable bank paper. The legislature
tried intermittently but unsuccessfully to
control circulation and to end
unauthorized banking. The shortage of capital, most
deeply felt in Cincinnati, the
Northwest's most important trade center, was critical.
Thus it was that the two branches of the
Bank of the United States, one in Cincinnati
and one in Chillicothe, were accepted in
Ohio.8
6. Ibid., 27, 37, 42-44, 51, 117-119, 196, 327.
7. "Mercantile Biography: Abbott
Lawrence: The Man, The Merchant, The Statesman,"
Hunt's Merchants' Magazine, XXXIV (January 1856), 46-56; Hamilton Andrews Hill, Memoir
of Abbott Lawrence (Boston, 1884), 1-10, 23-33; John Quincy Adams, Memoirs
of John
Quincy Adams (Philadelphia, 1876), X, 43; Jean Alexander Wilburn, Biddle's
Bank: The
Crucial Years (New York, 1967), 76-78.
The Lawrence family, founders of
Lawrence, Massachusetts, were never involved in invest-
ments in western banks or industry.
Abbott Lawrence to Ewing, November 14, 1840, Box 41,
Ewing Papers.
8. Charles Clifford Huntington, "A
History of Banking and Currency in Ohio Before the
Civil War," Ohio Archaeological
and Historical Quarterly, XXIV (July 1915), 266, 271-286,
294-296, 350; Richard Terrence Farrell,
"Cincinnati in the Early Jackson Era, 1816-1834: An
Economic and Political Study"
(unpublished Ph.D. dissertation, Indiana University, 1967),
49-57, 64-65, 72-74, 78-80, 85.
Seven cities in Ohio, many containing
old and established banks, requested a branch of the
national bank, citing expanded business
activity once Ohio's canal system was completed.
Wilburn, Biddle's Bank, 58.
8
OHIO HISTORY
At the outset, however, the Bank
overextended and then contracted loans and
oppressed local banks through its
western branches, engendering deep-seated ani-
mosities. A major source of opposition
arose from the Bank's almost virtual control
of the business area of Cincinnati and
rich farm lands which it acquired in liquidation
of debts as a result of the Panic of
1819. Added to this was the furor caused by the
state's attempts in 1819 to tax the
Bank's branches at Cincinnati and Chillicothe.
Also, charges were made that the Bank
tried to influence both the Ohio and national
legislators through loans granted to
them. In later years the Bank's supply of capital
and uniform currency wiped out much of
this ill will.9
As Ohio's economy recovered from the
1819 Panic, the need for a national bank
became greater. After 1827 the state's
circulation was 4 to 5 percent of the Bank's
total note issue. In 1830 it was $649,615;
by 1832, $1,130,475. The Bank's circula-
tion was usually in a one to five ratio
with state issues. In 1820 Ohio banks had a
circulation of $1,203,869; in 1835,
$5,221,520. The Bank contributed substantially
to Ohio's development as an important
source of capital and by facilitating the flow
of capital from financial centers to the
West. Between January 1811 and July 1830,
eighteen Ohio banks failed or
discontinued their business, taking out bank capital of
$1,911,179, leaving only eleven banks
with a capital of $1,454,386 to serve the needs
of the state. With less good banking
services than Ohio's economic growth and
rapid extension of commercial
agriculture required, the federal Bank's loans and
exchange dealings which financed the
movement of Ohio's major exports, were
welcome. In 1825 the Bank loaned
$1,939,000. Between 1828 and 1832, the nine
offices of the West and Southwest
increased their loans from one-third to one-half
of the total granted by the Bank. Ohio's
share was 8.4 percent, a monthly average
of loans outstanding of $3,539,390, in
1830; 8.3 percent, $5,508,725, two years
later; and 7 percent, $3,519,180, in
1834. Ewing told Congress in 1832:
This bank [Bank of the U. S.] was little
needed in that portion of our country where capital
has been accumulating for ages, and
therefore abounds. It was not wanted in Boston . . .
but in the West.... In these sections of
our country ... accumulated capital ... cannot,
exist; and there, of all places else, is
there need of capital.... By lending freely in this
youthful section of our country [the
Bank] did wisely . . . for the general benefit of the
nation.10
Revisionist studies show that the Bank
of the United States had a limited
potential to be a central bank but did
not fully utilize its tools. It did carry out the
central banking functions of supplying a
uniform currency and being an efficient
9. Ralph C. H. Catterall, The Second
Bank of the United States (Chicago, 1903), 51, 62-67,
77-91, 96-99, 113, 223-224, 249-255,
380-381, 401-411, 418-419, 430-446, 451-452; Wilburn,
Biddle's Bank, 47-51, 64, 131.
10. Catterall, Second Bank of the
United States, 137-141; Henry Adams, ed., The Writings
of Albert Gallatin (Philadelphia, 1879), III, 356-358, 362-364; Wilburn, Biddle's
Bank, 49;
Davis R. Dewey, The Second United
States Bank (Washington, D.C., 1910), IV, 200; House
Executive Documents, 21 Cong., 2 Sess., No. 63, pp. 8-79; ibid., 23
Cong., 1 Sess., No. 523,
pp. 74-145, 218-247; Senate
Documents, 23 Cong., 2 Sess., No. 8, pp. 2-43; Register of
Debates, 22 Cong., 1 Sess., VIII, 1249, 1254-1255.
Loans in Ohio are taken to be those
granted by the branch bank in Cincinnati and the
agencies in that city and Chillicothe.
Loan data is figured from the monthly statements of
the bank.
Thomas Ewing 9
fiscal agent,11 and it is
highly probable that the Bank would have continued its
development into a true central bank if
its charter had been renewed. It did succeed
admirably in providing a national
currency by increasing the total issue of its own
uniform notes and by returning state
bank notes for redemption in specie, in Bank
notes, or in bills of exchange. Because
state bank notes were redeemable, they
became sound and tended to circulate at
par. The quality of the money supply was
also improved after 1820 by stricter
state laws relating to specie redemption and to
the development of inter-bank balances
which made notes redeemable in distant
places. For many reasons Ohio bank notes
were considered to be more sound than
other western bank notes. Between 1821
and 1834, the Bank of the United States
and the banks of Ohio supplied
practically all the bank notes for the West that
circulated beyond state lines. This was
because the great number of bank failures
in the depression of 1819 precipitously
reduced the banks which issued notes. Those
institutions which remained, notably the
state chartered banks in Illinois and Ken-
tucky, issued irredeemable bank notes
which did not circulate beyond their imme-
diate locality.12
The Bank of the United States was able
by its size also to affect the economy and
to offset small changes in the money
supply mainly by varying its own currency.
However, the Bank was limited in
regulating economic expansion and contraction
because it was not the sole supplier of
currency nor the sole reservoir of specie.
Evidence shows that against notes and
deposits banks maintained small specie
reserves, the circulation issued was not
sensitive to the amount of specie on hand,
and an observable contraction of specie
did not lead to a contraction in notes or
deposits. What local banks seemed to
fear was that the national Bank would all but
exhaust their supply of specie. Analysis
reveals that the Bank behaved more often
as a large, powerful commercial bank
than as a central bank. That is, instead of
acting counter cyclically it acted
cyclically and, with its size, exacerbated expansion
or contraction. Some countercyclical
behavior was necessitated by the Bank's desire
for self-preservation and profit rather
than the achievement of national monetary
stability. Many state banks would not
have needed its aid if the Bank had not
acted drastically on its own behalf
first. The Bank's treatment of the Ohio banks
in the crisis of 1818-1819, when it
suddenly called in a tremendous sum of loans,
is an excellent case in point. Only
twice did the Bank utilize its rediscounting tools
and act as a true central bank: during
the contraction of 1828-1829 and part of the
expansion of 1829-1833. Once it acted as
a lender of last resort--in the contraction
of 1825-1826.13
If the Bank of the United States was not
a true central bank, why did Thomas
11. David G. Hayes, "The Second
Bank of the United States as a Central Bank" (unpub-
lished M.A. thesis, Brown University,
1959), 1-15; Joseph Van Fenstermaker, The Develop-
ment of American Commercial Banking:
1782-1837 (Kent, 0., 1965), 75-76;
Harold Barger,
The Management of Money (Chicago, 1966), 22-23.
12. Hayes, "Second Bank of the
United States," 6-8, 11; Catterall, Second Bank of the
United States, 96-97, 113, 430; Barger, Management of Money, 19-21;
Fenstermaker, Ameri-
can Commercial Banking, 28, 36, 39, 42-45, 90-91, 94.
Section One of an Ohio banking
law passed in the Ohio house on January 6, 1821, provided
that "every bank" which shall
refuse to redeem its notes when presented for payment in
specie, "such refusal shall be, and
the same is hereby declared to be a forfeiture of the
charter of such bank." Ohio, House
Journal, 1820-21, p. 239.
13. Hayes, "Second Bank of the
United States," 10-20, 33-41; Fenstermaker, American
Commercial Banking, 69-76, 99; Barger, Management of Money, 23.
10 OHIO
HISTORY
Ewing and the Whigs want it? The Whig
position held that Congress made a national
bank the agency responsible for monetary
policy and that the bank should utilize its
powers in the public interest to supply
a uniform currency, regulate credit, provide
as well as attract capital, and
stabilize economic growth.14 Ewing's main concern
in 1832 was the recharter of a properly
restricted national bank that would provide a
universally convertible currency and
capital and would regulate but not oppress the
local institutions. He opposed weakening
the Bank's role as a fiscal agent and refused
to set what he considered a poor
precedent of paying interest on volatile government
demand deposits. And he voted against
requiring state assent for the establishment
of branches.
Thomas Ewing's major contribution to the
new charter concerned the Bank's
circulation, which he wanted to be
acceptable at par everywhere. He thus objected
to limiting payment of $50 notes and
less only at the branches where issued. The
Ohio Senator introduced the amendment in
1832 which provided that although a
note was payable only at a particular
branch, it was to be received by the Bank at
any of its offices if tendered in
payment of any balance due the Bank from the state
banks. Horace Binney, the Bank's
lobbyist, communicated to Ewing that the Bank's
president, Nicholas Biddle, did not wish
the amendment adopted. Whereupon Ewing
told Binney that he was "determined
upon this clause" and warned him that "many
of the Western members would not vote
for the renewal without some such clause."
The amendment would end the slight
depreciation which existed when notes were
redeemed and would insure strict
convertibility everywhere, thereby resulting in
freer circulation. The Bank's ability to
place a measure of limited restraint over state
bank issues was weakened, however,
because the state banks could draw specie for
notes not issued by the particular
branch at which the notes were offered. This would
tend to increase the state bank reserves
on which more notes could be issued.15
In 1832 Ewing reflected the sentiments
of most Ohioans who felt the national bank
was needed to insure continued economic
development of the West. Claims that the
state banks resented the federal
institution are simply not true in Ohio after the effect
of Nicholas Biddle's policy, which
increased capital in the West, became noticeable.
Support for the Bank remained strong in
Cincinnati and local bankers did not
actively oppose the branch. Citizens
signed sixteen petitions, and four large state
banks sent memorials to Congress praying
for recharter. An Ohio Democrat ex-
pressed a widespread feeling when he
asserted: "Refuse to re-charter the bank, and
Pittsburgh, Cincinnati . . . and New
Orleans, will be crushed at one blow."16
The vote on recharter showed that the
West favored a national bank. Ohio's
Whig Senators, Thomas Ewing and Benjamin
Ruggles, voted yes. In the lower house,
ten of the state's Representatives voted
yes, three against and one was absent. It
was not a strictly party nor sectional
vote; of those favorable, six were National
Republicans and four were Democrats, and
they were representative of all the
14. Richard H. Timberlake, Jr., Money,
Banking, and Central Banking (New York, 1965),
159-160, 167.
15. Register of Debates, 22 Cong., 1 Sess., VIII, 948, 964, 980, 989, 1007,
1021, 1045;
Horace Binney to Nicholas Biddle,
February 14, 1832, Vol. 31, Nicholas Biddle Papers,
Manuscript Division, Library of
Congress; Catterall, Second Bank of the United States, 236-
237, 429.
16. Farrell, "Cincinnati in the
JacksOn Era," 50-51, 74, 78-85, 230; Wilburn, Biddle's Bank,
37, 45, 51-53, 63-65, 129, 131-135;
Arthur Schlesinger, Jr., The Age of Jackson (Boston,
1946), 77-78.
Thomas Ewing 11
economic regions of the state. All
opposed were Democrats. The President vetoed
the bill.17
In a lengthy speech on July 11, 1832,
Ewing attacked a number of the major
points in Jackson's veto message and
listed what he felt were the major benefits of a
national bank. He showed that the Bank's
borrowers were "the young, the active, and
the enterprising"--not the rich as
Jackson had claimed. The Ohio Senator declared
the national bank's ability to attract
foreign capital was of great importance. "Ought
we to complain that foreigners come here
and lend their money or invest their
capital? ... [D]oes Ohio feel grieved
that her stock is owned in ... London? No
such thing. It is, of all others, that
which advances our prosperity." In fact, lack
of capital prevented the United States
from competing with foreign manufactured
goods.18
Ewing argued further that the Bank's
loans had financed much of Ohio's growth
and the calling in of these loans would
affect the state banks and set back economic
development since there was no longer
any free capital available for banking. "[T]he
necessities of the country do at present
require this institution. .... [The] bank ...
is the ... invigorating principle of our
whole moneyed system .. . [T]here is no bank,
and no individual . . . whatever be his
occupation . . . but is, in a greater or less
degree, directly or indirectly,
connected in and through his daily avocations with the
Bank . . . and its issues." The
shipment of specie to Europe, as foreign capital was
repatriated, would cause severe
pressures on the money market. Ohio's banks,
pressured for specie, would stop lending
and would be forced to withdraw their
issues, causing a drastic fall in
prices.19
Andrew Jackson's veto of the national
bank charter and the Panic of 1837 and
ensuing seven-year depression had
economic and political consequences of great
significance in Ohio. The first effect
was a rapid expansion of the money supply,
but one that consisted of a varigated
currency which fluctuated in value in proportion
to the distance from the place of
redemption. A second result was high exchange
rates. And, third, capital became less
available. Efforts to improve the currency
affected the supply of capital since
note issue served currency, credit, and long-term
capital functions. Thus the expansion of
banks in the 1830's differs from the standard
interpretation that state banks rushed
to fill the vacuum created by the demise of
the federal bank. Instead, the increase
in the number of chartered and reorganized
banks reflected the great scarcity of
capital and a need beyond that supplied by the
national bank and the eleven state
banks. In 1839 Ohio had thirty-five authorized
banks. At the same time a significant
amount of banking was carried on by about
thirty unauthorized banks opened in
response to the critical conditions caused by
the depression. Eastern capital,
attracted by the canal regions and as a way of
17. Wilburn, Biddle's Bank, 6-9,
133; House Journal, 22 Cong., 1 Sess., 1074-1075.
18. Register of Debates, 22
Cong., 1 Sess., VIII 1252-1254. Foreign loans were the least
burdensome way of acquiring capital for
the state's canal program.
The Bank of Cincinnati concurred in
Ewing's analysis which was in contravention of the
typical Jacksonian line derailing the
small ownership of stock in the West (712 shares in
Ohio). Senate Documents, 22
Cong., 1 Sess., No. 68.
19. Register of Debates, 23
Cong., 1 Sess., X, 301-329, 1291-1295, 1597-1599, 1728-1729,
1781-1782; ibid., 22 Cong., 1
Sess., VIII, 1256-1257.
As a member of the powerful Finance
Committee, Ewing assisted in the final investigation
of the Bank of the United States in late
1834. He inquired into the trade and currency of
the West, distributing a questionnaire
covering twenty points. The final report approved the
Bank's policies. Senate Documents, 23
Cong., 1 Sess., No. 17.
12 OHIO
HISTORY
profiting from the speculative land
boom, made possible much of the bank expansion.
By 1833, $3.3 million of $4.7 million of
banking capital in Ohio was owned by
nonresidents; in 1840, one-half was
foreign owned.20 As the banks were forced to
diversify their limited resources,
capital became less available and in all probability
helped to prolong the depression.
Western banks faced two major problems
which grew progressively more acute
after the national bank closed:
maintenance of circulation and preservation of specie
reserves. Without bank notes there would
have been very little money in circulation.
Financial success thus was dependent
upon the ability to keep notes circulating, and
banks resorted to all sorts of schemes
to prevent their notes from returning for
redemption. Political influence was used
to have the state distribute a particular
bank's notes far from the home office.
Cooperative efforts whereby two distant banks
circulated their notes in each other's
cities were also effective.21 The prospect of a
large and unexpected demand for specie
was an ever-present danger for the banker
operating without a central bank to
which he could turn in an emergency. Deliberate
intra-state bank warfare and specie
raids added to the hazards of western finance.
Loans were often affected by a desire to
protect as well as increase specie reserves.
Not only was a customer's credit
worthiness and collateral taken into account, but
also consideration of where the money
was to be spent, with an attempt to ensure
a slow return of notes for redemption or
an increase of specie through repayment
in eastern funds.22
An important part of the credit demand
was related to the export of the agricultural
surplus to eastern and southern markets.
The ability of Ohio's banks to lend often
determined whether business was done or
shipments made at all. Between 1839 and
1843 discounted bills of exchange,
important financial instruments for the export
trade, were between 31 and 43 percent of
total loans. Local banks were forced to
divert over a third of their scarce
capital to a sector once financed by the national
bank. Had a federal institution been
able to supply this capital the local banks would
have been able to finance other sectors
of the economy.
Western banks helped to support the
rapidity of migration and settlement. They
also had a great deal to do with the
speculative land boom and the bunching of
projects in a short time. Many long-term
loans, often based on government deposits
and extended after a small percentage
was repaid, were used for improvements, and
the credit terms offered were attractive
to settlers. The land boom was drastically
curtailed in 1836 when President Jackson
issued the Specie Circular. This directive
required payment in coin for public
lands. Ewing fought to rescind this measure
because it threw purchasers into the
arms of speculators who would accept bank
notes. Other burdens placed on the state
banks were the considerable demands for
capital made by the internal improvement
agencies, both public and private.23
Thus by 1840, without the national bank
and with the stability of the state banks
20. Carter H. Golembe, "State Banks
and the Economic Development of the West, 1830-
1844" (unpublished Ph.D.
dissertation, Columbia University, 1952), 2, 50-51, 210-212, 217,
220-226, 230-240; Paul B. Trescott, Financing
American Enterprise (New York, 1963), 16-17,
22, 25, 264-265, 268; Harry N. Scheiber,
"The Commercial Bank of Lake Erie, 1831-1843,"
Business History Review, XI (Spring 1966), 49-54, 63-65.
21. Golembe, "State Banks,"
54-55, 58-62a, 65-66, 74-79, 213n, 249; William E. and Ophia
D. Smith, A Buckeye Titan (Cincinnati,
1953), 240-253, 270, 276, 296, 300, 311-312.
22. Golembe, "State Banks,"
62a-73, 117, 225, 249; Smith, Buckeye Titan, 243-244, 288-292.
23. Golembe, "State Banks,"
81-84, 89-101, 112-124, 135-139, 143-149, 154-167, 187, 207-
208, 225-239, 249; Congressional
Globe, 24 Cong., 2 Sess., 10, 17, 35, Appendix, 11-14.
Thomas Ewing 13
in doubt, a need was increasingly being
felt for the establishment of a central banking
facility to restore order to the chaotic
financial conditions. Whigs and Democrats
each recommended solutions to the
crisis, solutions that were to have important
repercussions on American financial and
banking history. There was a great
divergence as to the meaning and
direction of America's development. Whig doctrine
declared that a balanced economy,
financed by bank credit, was essential to economic
development of the country. The
Democratic party was seriously split by the
depression which enabled the doctrinaire
hard-money faction, hostile to the develop-
ment of a business community,
corporations, banks, and paper money, to gain
control nationally and in Ohio. These
radical hard-money Jacksonians blamed the
depression on the banks' inflationary
extension of credit. Their solution was the
establishment of the Independent
Treasury under which the Government would be
completely divorced from the banks, and
they worked for the end of the banks in
Ohio. The conservative or soft-money
Democrats, on the other hand, held that the
banks must be better regulated,
political influence in the granting of charters stopped,
the issue of notes by any but chartered
banks forbidden, and the circulation of small
notes restricted. The only effective
reform in Ohio was pioneering legislation passed
in 1839 providing for three state bank
commissioners to make surprise visits to the
banks once a year to examine their
books. Political animosities and deeply held
views prevented passage of long-term,
realistic, and meaningful reforms.24 To
Thomas Ewing, who asserted that
Democratic hard-money policies were inadequate
for the growth of Ohio and America, this
situation only increased the urgency for
a national bank.
The excitement of the Whig campaign in
1840 found wide appeal because of its
diversions from the pressures of
America's first major depression. Ewing, one of
the Whig's foremost orators, and
Lawrence showed great enthusiasm for William
Henry Harrison because he would consider
a national bank. Behind the ballyhoo
there was some discussion of issues--the
economy, the currency, and a national
bank. Ewing stated: "Our opponents
were gravely raising and debating the question
whether [the Bank] was convenient or
necessary." Daniel Webster sketched the
outlines of a bank, noting its central
banking functions "in case local panics should
occur, to relieve the community, by [an]
adaptation of the amount of outstanding
circulation." Harrison told a large
Dayton audience of 100,000 he would sign a
bank bill if a bank was found necessary
and demanded by a majority of the people.
The Whigs won with 53 percent of the
vote: 1,275,612 for Harrison, and 1,130,033
for Martin Van Buren. They handily
carried Ohio and Massachusetts.25
As soon as the results were in, the
Cabinet became a topical subject. The Wash-
24. Van Deusen, Jacksonian Era, 11-12,
22-25, 119; James Roger Sharp, The Jacksonians
Versus the Banks: Politics in the
United States After the Panic of 1837 (New
York, 1970), 5-6,
14-18, 24, 44, 130-131, 209. One of the
political repercussions was the defeat of Ewing for his
Senate seat in 1840 by William Allen, a
hard-money Democrat par excellence.
The Independent Treasury Act was finally
passed during the Van Buren administration in
1840 and was repealed by the Whigs in
1841. The deposit system of the government was not
regulated by law until 1846 when the
Democrats revived the act. This legislation served without
important change as the basis of U. S.
government's relationship to the banking system until
passage of the Federal Reserve Act in
1913.
25. Ewing to L. D. Barker, July [18?],
1840, in "Documents: Diary of Thomas Ewing, August
and September, 1841," American
Historical Review, XVIII (October 1912), 108; Daniel
Webster, The Works of Daniel Webster (Boston,
1851), II, 61; Niles' National Register, LIX
(October 3, 1840), 71; Arthur M.
Schlesinger, Jr., and Fred L. Israel, eds., History of American
Presidential Elections (New York, 1971), I, 685-690.
14 OHIO
HISTORY
ington Globe cried: "No one
will be ... appointed who is not a friend to BIDDLE'S
BANK."26 One man who was
highly influential in helping Harrison choose his
Cabinet was Abbott Lawrence. Just two
days after the election, Lawrence wrote to
Ewing: "We have chosen you into
Gen. Harrison's Cabinet--therefore prepare
yourself to go to Washington." He also wrote John J. Crittenden, recently designated
Attorney-General, on January 7
concerning "the positive necessity of having a
Secretary of the Treasury who has the
confidence of the people . . . it is the most
important office in the govt.... I ...
am confirmed in the opinion that our friend
Thomas Ewing is ... the best man....
Ewing is with and of the people ... as well
as the monied interest of the
country have confidence in him."27 The opinions of
the New England capitalist carried great
weight; Thomas Ewing became Secretary
of the Treasury.
After Harrison's inaugural address in
which he declared against an exclusively
metallic currency, Lawrence continued in
frequent consultation with Harrison's
Cabinet and dined with the President.
Just before he returned to Boston, Lawrence
called on his good friend John Quincy
Adams and assured him that "Ewing is for
banks." On April 2, Lawrence wrote
Ewing from Boston: "I hope . . . you will
make the Treasury strong."28
Two days later William Henry Harrison
was dead, the first President to die in
office. He was succeeded by John Tyler
who had been nominated to appeal to the
states rights faction of the Whig party.
Tyler had left the Democratic party in
protest over Jackson's removal of the
government deposits from the Bank of the
United States, which he held was
executive usurpation and contrary to the principle
of government by law. Tyler, however,
continued to adhere to the Democratic view
that a national bank was
unconstitutional since there was no direct provision for
one in the Constitution. Nevertheless,
Tyler had supported Harrison's position in
the campaign at St. Clairsville and
Steubenville, and in a letter to citizens of Virginia
he had adopted the language of Harrison
declaring: "Now if 'the power granted'
could not be carried into effect without
incorporating a Bank, then it becomes
'necessary and proper,' and of course
expedient.. ."29 Some Whig leaders, however,
were uneasy about the new President's
policies. For example, Alfred Kelley of Ohio
wrote Ewing:
Considerable anxiety is felt... as to
the course which the Vice President will pursue. I...
feel confident, as do most of our
political friends ... that he will adopt the views of the late
President and carry them out with
religious fidelity.30
26. The Globe (Washington, D.
C.), December 17, 1840.
27. Lawrence to Ewing, November 14,
1840, Box 41, Ewing Papers; Lawrence to John J.
Crittenden, January 7, 1841, Vol. 7,
John J. Crittenden Papers, Manuscript Division, Library of
Congress.
28. James D. Richardson, ed., A
Compilation of the Messages and Papers of the Presidents
(Washington, D. C., 1897), IV, 14;
Adams, John Q. Adams, X, 438, 443-445; Lawrence to
Ewing, April 2, 1841, Box 43, Ewing
Papers.
29. Oliver Perry Chitwood, John Tyler:
Champion of the Old South (New York, 1939),
114-115, 126-139, 185-191, 476-477; John
Tyler to Citizens of Henrico County, Virginia, Octo-
ber 6, 1840, letter in Defence of the
President Against the Attacks of Mr. Botts and the Clay
Party (1843), 3.
30. Alfred Kelley to Ewing, April 9,
1841, Box 43, Ewing Papers. Kelley (1789-1859), a lead-
ing figure in the development and
administration of Ohio's canal system, later wrote the legisla-
tion (Act of 1845) which reformed Ohio's
banking system.
Thomas Ewing 15
On April 9, 1841, Tyler addressed the
nation: "A permanent and radical change
should ... be decreed" in the
country's finances. "I shall promptly give my sanction
to any constitutional measure which . .
. shall have for its object the restoration of
a sound circulating medium, so
essentially necessary . . . to reestablish the public
prosperity." Tyler added the caveat
that in deciding upon the measure he would
resort to the example of the great
Republican school.31 Despite the fact that the
country was once again in the hands of a
strict constructionist and that Tyler's words
were open to varying interpretations,
the Whigs felt encouraged to go forward with
their plans for a bank.
There had been calls for a national bank
as soon as the campaign ended. On
November 20 an old acquaintance told
Ewing: "I . . . would be glad to see a bill
introduced in the next Congress for a
National, a truly National Bank." Christmas
Day the Cincinnati Chronicle called
for the establishment of a national bank to
provide a uniform currency. The urgency
for a national bank was acutely felt by
the Ohio Whigs because the charters of
most Ohio banks were due to expire in
1843 and the state would be left without
an adequate supply of capital.32
Abbott Lawrence hoped that he could
personally "take part in the settlement of
a few prominent questions [including]
those concerning the currency." On April 5,
he wrote Ewing that despite Harrison's death
the work of reform should go on and
anticipated that Congress would set
forth a series of measures "boldly and fearlessly
disclosing our intentions."
Lawrence continued, "I shall begin upon the Bank this
week and hope by the advice and
assistance of our friends to produce a practical
charter--that will be satisfactory to the People, the Government
and the Capitalist."
Toward the end of the month, however,
Lawrence confessed that he had just
commenced upon the bank project, finding
it "full of difficulties," but hoped that he
would be able to produce something that
"will give you a tolerable degree of
satisfaction." He continued:
It is a very delicate matter to adjust
the provisions of a bank to meet the wishes of a
majority of the Representatives of the
people,--retain the functions which should belong
to such an Institution, and satisfy the
capitalists of the Country--This cannot be done,
and adopt the views of the Virginia
School of Politicians.
Lawrence was able to forward to Ewing
the outline for a bank on May 6, with
apologies for his tardiness:
When I left Washington it was my
intention to have sent to you the outline of a Bank of
the United States very soon after my
return home--but I have been so constantly
engaged that I have not found time to do
more than to give you the "legs and wings" of a
Bank.... I should have been glad to have
sent you a Charter complete written out... it
is however quite impossible for me to go
through the detail till next month, when I shall
have the time, but too late for you--...
Look on it as I submit it to you--if explanations
are required I should be happy to
furnish them.33
31. Richardson, Papers of the
Presidents, IV, 37-39.
32. J. W. Coffinburg to Ewing, November
20, 1840, Box 41, Ewing Papers; Edgar Allan Holt,
Party Politics in Ohio, 1840-1850 (Columbus, 1930), 157.
33. Hill, Abbott Lawrence, 59;
Lawrence to Ewing, April 5, 23, 1841, (Private & Confidential),
July 5, 1841, Box 43, 44, Ewing Papers;
Lawrence to Ewing, May 6, 1841, A. Lawrence Papers,
Massachusetts Historical Society. The
"Virginia School of Politicians" were the extreme states
rights oriented politicians, most of
whom came from Virginia.
16
OHIO HISTORY
In the meantime, Tyler had also been
giving serious thought to the bank. On
April 30 he wrote to Henry Clay.
"As to a Bank, I design to be perfectly frank with
you--I would not have it urged
prematurely.... I desire you to consider whether
you cannot so frame a Bank as to avoid
all constitutional objections. . . ." To avoid
a deadlock it was also important that a
clash between the nationalist views of Henry
Clay and the states rights principles of
John Tyler be averted, but Ewing was
encouraged that Tyler seemed open to
proposals from Congress that would meet his
constitutional scruples.34
On June 1 the President sent a message
to Congress calling for a suitable fiscal
agent capable of collecting and
disbursing the public moneys, adding, "Upon such
an agent depends in an eminent degree
the establishment of a currency of uniform
value...." Tyler warned Congress
that he reserved the ultimate power of rejection.
The following day Secretary of the
Treasury Ewing sent his annual report to
Congress. Strongly recommending the
establishment of a bank, he stated, "Experi-
ence has demonstrated the superior
utility of a bank, constituted and adapted by
Congress as a fiscal agent." The
Secretary was "irresistibly led to the conclusion"
that such a fiscal agent was
"essential to the wants of the Treasury and of the com-
munity" and would produce
"important benefits on the country." On June 7, Con-
gress asked Ewing for a plan of a bank
free from constitutional objections. On June
12, Ewing submitted his plan. It appears
from the Ewing-Lawrence correspondence
that Lawrence's ideas and draft charter
were an important basis for Ewing's bill. In
early July, Lawrence wrote the Secretary,
"After your plan came out, it was said,
and published in the papers that
I was the author of it." Ewing knew that Tyler
would not surrender his lifelong
position on states rights and so tried to make his
plan to meet the President's approval.
Tyler, attempting to find a common ground
between his views and those of the bank
proponents, had recommended to Ewing
that he frame his bill for a bank in
accordance with a scheme that Congress establish
a bank in the District of Columbia where
it had constitutional authority. The
President sincerely felt that this
expediency solved the constitutional issue of whether
or not Congress had the power to
establish a bank.35
Henry Clay, on the other hand, wanted a
bank created by Congress with power
to establish branches where national
economic growth demanded. If Ewing had
chosen Clay's position, the President
would never have accepted the bill and there
would have been no chance for a bank. If
he took some of Tyler's scruples into
34. Tyler to Henry Clay, April 30, 1841,
in Lyon G. Tyler, ed., The Letters and Times of the
Tylers (Williamsburg, 1896), III, 93; Ewing to Clay, May 8,
1841, Vol. 23, Henry Clay Papers,
Manuscript Division, Library of
Congress.
35. President Tyler seemed to be trying
to revive an old idea that had earlier failed for lack
of support. In 1819 the State of
Pennsylvania proposed to the consideration of the state legis-
latures an amendment to the Constitution
that provided "Congress shall make no law to erect or
incorporate any bank or other monied
institution except within the District of Columbia, & every
bank, or other monied institution which
shall be established by the authority of congress, shall,
together with its branches and offices
of discount and deposit, be confined to the District of
Columbia." The legislature of Ohio
agreed to the proposal on January 19, 1820, without the
senate's statement on the
constitutionality of the bank. The Ohio house held that the con-
stitutionality of the bank was not at
issue here, and it would resolve on December 28, 1820, that
the Bank of the United States was a
"private corporation of trade" and therefore legally taxable.
Ohio, Senate Journal, 1819-20, pp.
116-117, 188, 193; House Journal, 1820-21, p. 193; Richard-
son, Papers of the Presidents, IV,
40-51; Secretary of the Treasury, Report on the Finances,
1837-1844 (Washington, D. C., 1851), IV, 446-447; Lawrence to
Ewing, July 5, 1841, Vol. 6,
Box 44, Ewing Papers.
Thomas Ewing 17
account, a bank might be chartered.
Ewing's compromise plan provided for a
$30,000,000 bank in the District of
Columbia, one-fifth of the stock to be taken by
the Federal Government. Loans to the
Government would be limited to $3,000,000
for 180 days; loans to the states
$100,000; and, recognizing the West's need for
longer credit terms, other loans could
run for a maximum of 180 days, would not be
renewable, and would cease when
circulation reached three times the amount of
specie, preventing inflationary
tendencies. The bank notes, of a minimum denomina-
tion of ten dollars, were to be issued
only by the parent bank and were redeemable on
demand. As the fiscal agent of the
Government, its notes were acceptable for public
dues. Ewing's bill, taking cognizance of
Tyler's states rights views, proposed that
the bank would only establish branches
with a state's consent, but once established
the branch could not be withdrawn
without congressional assent. The bank was also
empowered to employ agencies, without
state consent, to transact all business, such
as accepting deposits and dealing in
bills of exchange, except discounting--that is,
the granting of loans. And Congress
would retain the option of placing offices of
discount and deposit where necessary for
handling the public revenue. Ewing's
charter, which envisaged the concept of
monetary control, would have created an
institution that could have developed
into a central bank. Because of Tyler's stand
in the campaign and statements in his
two addresses as President, it was understood
that he would sanction Ewing's plan.
Tyler even urged Clay to support it.36
Merchants from the principal cities were
invited to Washington to discuss the
Secretary's proposal, and they promised
to support the bank. Webster thought
Ewing's plan the only one on which
agreement in Congress could be reached.
Horace Greeley also enthusiastically
favored the charter and announced, "The
crippled Commerce, the prostrate
Enterprise, the disjointed Currency of the Country,
all require a National Bank."37
Clay, however, rejected the critical
parts of Ewing's draft, and on June 21 reported
out a bill chartering a bank with power
to branch without state assent. He felt that
without the power to branch the bank
would be devoid of effective national character.
Furthermore, a derivation of power to
the Federal Government from the states
would be unsound in principle and
dangerous. The Senate leader thus replaced
Ewing's attempt at compromise with
ultra-Whig demands. The opposition of Clay
to the Secretary of the Treasury's bill
aroused debate within the Whig party. Ultra
Whigs disliked a bank that compromised
their nationalist views, while the moderates
stood behind Ewing. Lawrence wrote from
Massachusetts on July 5:
Your plan as a whole does not
meet the approbation of our people.... Mr. Clay's plan
meets with more favor.... I am not wedded
to my own plan--or opinions, and am quite
ready to make every concession that can
be desired--provided such concessions do not
involve principles upon which the
success and usefulness of the Bank depends.
Support for the Treasury Secretary came
from Ewing's Ohio friends:
As between the plan [you] suggested . .
. and that contended for by Mr. Clay our friends
are a good deal divided. But as far as I
can judge the Treasury plan has the most friends.
... [M]any pronounce the plan submitted
by yourself as the product of necessity being
36. Tyler, Letters of the Tylers, II,
54, 68-69; Senate Documents, 27 Cong., 1 Sess., No. 17;
Timberlake, Money and Banking, 167-168;
Chitwood, John Tyler, 220.
37. Ibid.; Log Cabin (New York),
June 12, 19, 1841.
18 OHIO
HISTORY
made as is supposed to escape the
president's Veto. And reasoning in the same way it is
feared that a bill upon the basis
advocated by Mr. Clay will not receive the President's
sanction.
* * *
I find the Great mass of Whigs (I mean
the middle class) opposed to Mr. Clay's Bank bill,
and in favor of the one recommended by
you.... Democrats are willing to go for Mr.
Ewing's plan. It is every where said if
we must have a Bank let us have Mr. Ewing's plan.38
The debates in Congress revolved around
two principle points. One basic question,
whether or not the country needed a
national bank to regulate economic growth, was
contested by the Whigs and the
Democrats. The hard-money radicals dominated the
Democratic position and supported the
Independent Treasury system, opposing the
Whig proposal of a national bank. The
second question, the kind of national bank
which Congress would be likely to
charter and the President would approve, was
debated among the Whigs. At stake, in
the moderate view, was the chance to
reestablish a national bank; in the
ultra-Whig view, the retention of a nationally
oriented policy over narrow states
rights demands. Complicating and coloring the
Whig fight was Henry Clay's
determination to use the bank issue to gain the Presi-
dency, making him stubbornly opposed to
proposals from either Ewing or the
President.
The debate lasted six weeks. The
Democratic forces were led by Senator Benjamin
Tappan, the first advisor Tyler called
in upon his accession to the Presidency; Robert
Walker, the Democratic Senator from
Mississippi and a future Secretary of the
Treasury; and Thomas Hart Benton,
Senator from Missouri and the nation's most
outspoken advocate of the hard-money philosophy.
The Ohio Senators, Tappan and
William Allen, like Benton, were
hard-money Jacksonians, intransigent and uncom-
promising. In Ohio there was concern
lest Tappan's hard line upset alliances with
the conservatives. But in Congress
Tappan had the support of Tyler and knew that
the President would not sign any bill
creating a national bank of discount, regardless
of any states rights considerations.
Even though Clay attempted to railroad his bank
bill through Congress, the Democrats
were not put off easily. They spoke out against
the central banking provisions inherent
in the bill.39
The longest debates centered around the
branching issue. The moderates, realizing
that Clay's bill would never meet the
President's states rights strictures, proposed
changes. Virginia Senator William C.
Rives, a conservative Democrat who advocated
a regulated state banking system, was at
this time a leading supporter of Tyler's
views on the bank issue. He moved to
restore Ewing's provision in the bill allowing
for state assent for branch banks.
Senator Rufus Choate of Massachusetts, an
acknowledged authority on law and a
nationalist, reasoned that there was no sur-
38. "Report of a Fiscal
Agent," Senate Documents, 27 Cong., 1 Sess., No. 32; Lawrence to
Ewing, July 5, 1841, H. H. Hunter to
Ewing, July 10, 1841, James Cunningham to Ewing, July
29, 1841, Vol. 6, Box 44, Ewing Papers.
Hocking H. Hunter, one of Ohio's
pioneers, was an intimate friend and law partner of Ewing
and a Whig leader in Lancaster, Ohio.
Miller, "Thomas Ewing," 34, 282; New York Times,
Obituary, February 7, 1872.
39. Benjamin Tappan Senate Journal
(December 6, 1840-February 24, 1844), June 2, 8, 16,
25, 1841, Box 3, Benjamin Tappan Papers,
Ohio Historical Society; Sharp, Jacksonians Versus
the Banks, 18-19, 22; Congressional Globe, 27 Cong., 1
Sess., 157-158, 167-172, 177, 197-198,
234, 251, 278, Appendix, 194-197,
207-208. Pamphlets of the time also clearly pointed out a
national bank's central banking powers.
Thomas Ewing 19
render of constitutional power but that
it may not always be expedient to exert a
power. To moderate Whigs, many of whom
were as staunch nationalists as the ultra
Whigs, the passage of a bill providing
for a national bank to regulate the currency
and to promote business among the states
by an economical exchange was more
important than Clay's insistence that
the constitutionality of the power of Congress
to create a national bank was not an
issue for debate. To the ultra Whigs any other
than Clay's proposal meant a dangerous
relinquishing of national power. Their
priorities were not only for a bank but
also for the maintenance of the principle
of the power of Congress to charter a
bank.40 Ewing personally agreed with Clay's
position; he had publicly declared
against state assent eight years before. His primary
goal now, however, was a bank.
By a vote of thirty-eight to ten the
Rives amendment, allowing for state assent,
was defeated. Also defeated was a
proposal by Senator Richard Bayard of Delaware
which permitted the conversion of
agencies into offices of discount and deposit, that
is, branches empowered to grant loans.
Moderate Whigs in the business community
and the administration now took the
lead in reaching a compromise that would
please Clay and Tyler and result in a bank.
They were aided by the fact that Clay
realized his bill, as matters then stood, was
doomed to defeat.41 The chief
influence upon Clay was his old confidant Peter Buell
Porter of New York, one of the
architects of the Whig party. Porter arrived in
Washington at Clay's request and
proposed a compromise amendment to Clay. Each
state could prevent the establishment of
a branch bank by an act passed in the first
session of the state legislature after
the passage of the bill by Congress. If, however,
such legislation were not passed, the
state's assent to the establishment would be
presumed. Porter felt that Tyler would
"feel gratified in having a bill presented to
him so nearly accordant with his own
views." He suggested that Clay himself, as a
gesture of conciliation, introduce the
amendment. Porter neatly argued that without
such an amendment the legislatures of
many southern states would resent the affront
and forbid branches; whereas, with the
amendment they would abstain from such
action and would find they needed the
bank. It seems, however, that Clay had his
own plans and remained obdurate. Thus
Porter turned to Senator William Preston,
a moderate from South Carolina, for
support. Porter received Preston's agreement
to the amendment and showed it to
several members of Congress and to Clay on the
morning of July 20. Clay still did not
act and Porter wrote again on the twenty-first,
before he left Washington, holding that
the amendment was, as regarded the con-
stitutional difficulty, the best that
could be drawn up. It would leave the operations
as extensive as could be devised, but
nothing for its enemies to pounce upon. Even
Webster was advising conciliation. New
York Whigs supported Porter's plan and
would be gratified to see Clay make this
innocuous concession for the sake of
harmony. Clay finally yielded.42
John Minor Botts, a Whig Representative
from Virginia, offered to see if the
Porter proposal was as acceptable to
Tyler as it had been to the Whig caucus. Tyler
40. Ibid., 133, 141, 145, 152,
255, Appendix, 351-361.
41. Ibid., 145, 152.
42. Clay to Peter Buell Porter, April
24, June 30, July 18, 21, 1841; proposed letter from
[Porter] to Preston, July 20, 1841,
Charles Hammond Papers, Ohio Historical Society; Porter to
Clay, n.d., n.d. [pre-July 20], July 21,
23, 24, 1841, Peter Buell Porter Papers, Roll 12, Buffalo
and Erie County Historical Society.
20 OHIO
HISTORY
seemingly accepted the compromise. On
July 27 Clay offered the Porter amendment
so that his bill might pass. But Clay
further provided that Congress should have the
power to establish an office of unstated
function when necessary, regardless of the
state's position. In the Senate, the
amendment passed 25 to 24. The next day the
bill passed 26 to 23. Allen and Tappan,
the key man controlling Democratic votes,
voted no.43
Now Tyler began to claim he favored
Ewing's bill though Webster had earlier
informed Ewing that the Secretary's
original plan no longer pleased the President.
But the Clay version passed the House by
a vote of 128 to 97 on August 6.44
The
Ohio vote, twelve in favor and seven
opposed, was along strict party lines. Most of
the Democrats supported the radical
view. Most of the Whigs represented economi-
cally sophisticated areas: the Muskingum
Valley, one of the major producers of the
nation's corn, wheat, and pork, and the
rich Western Reserve and Scioto Valley, seat
of the state's cattle industry. Two
Representatives from the Scioto Valley, bisected
by the Ohio Canal, had supported the
bank in previous congressional votes and one
was later influential in the drafting of
Ohio's banking law. The moderately Demo-
cratic constituency of Cincinnati
realized the need for a national bank, but bank
views among Ohio's citizens were, with
certain exceptions, directly correlated with
economic development, and
Representatives of the poorer areas voted no.45
The Cabinet strongly advised the
President to sign the bill. The Secretary of the
Treasury set forth the nationalist views
of the Whigs: Congress was constitutionally
empowered to charter a bank with
branches with or without state assent. However,
he recognized that Tyler held other
views and in a tightly reasoned argument, of
which he was a master, demonstrated to
the President that signing the bill would
not conflict with his principles. Congress
could create a corporation in the District
of Columbia and implied assent for the
branches, falling within the comity of nations,
was presumed unless forbidden by law.
Ewing could find in this principle no violation
of the Constitution and no infringement
of the rights of the states.46
There is evidence that Tyler would have
signed the Treasury bill had it been
promptly passed, but Clay's plan was
totally unacceptable to the President.47 At the
time Ewing was preparing his argument,
Tappan reported in his journal, "it is
generally expected by all parties that
the President will veto it [Clay's bill]. I have
taken great pains to satisfy Tyler that
if he would veto that bill the Democratic party
would sustain him against Clay."
Tappan also told Rives that he should advise the
President that his veto should simply
state the Executive's objections and not be
accompanied with any recommendations
because the Democrats might be unable to
support them. A committee of Ohio
Representatives had prevailed upon Tyler to sign
the bill, but he admitted he would be
obliged to veto it; nevertheless, he would recom-
mend a bank he could approve. This
course was counter to Tappan's suggestions.
On August 16 Tyler vetoed the bill
giving four reasons against it. First, he thought
43. Chitwood, John Tyler, 222-223;
Congressional Globe, 27 Cong., 1 Sess., 254-256, 260,
Appendix, 362-366.
44. Tyler, Letters of the Tylers, II,
52; Congressional Globe, 27 Cong., 1 Sess., 303.
45. Sharp, Jacksonians Versus the
Banks, 160-168, 173-178, 184-188, 336-338. The designa-
tion of the political affiliations of
the counties of Ohio is based on Sharp's excellent analysis
and covers the years 1836 to 1844. Ibid.,
166n, 168n, 333-334, 344.
46. Van Deusen, Jacksonian Era, 157;
Ewing to His Excellency the President of the United
States [Bank Charter, 1841], Box 44,
Ewing Papers.
47. Tappan Senate Journal, June 12,
1841; Ewing to Tyler, September 11, 1841, in Niles'
Register, LXI (September 18, 1841), 34.
Thomas Ewing 21
a national bank was unconstitutional.
Throughout his career, Tyler had consistently
maintained that it was unconstitutional
for Congress to create a national bank to
operate over the nation. The
nationalists, including Ewing, asserted that Congress
did have the authority and that the
issue had long been settled.
Tyler next charged that a bank of
discount was not necessary for the government's
fiscal powers of collecting, keeping,
and disbursing the public revenues and incidently
regulating commerce and exchange. Local
transactions had nothing to do with
regulating the currency; it was the
exchange operations which effected a uniform
currency. Third, the bank was not properly
limited to dealing in exchange. The
nationalist Whig concept was also at
odds with these two objections relative to
banking functions. The Whigs did not
deny the invaluable role of exchange in
creating a uniform currency, but to
Ewing, Clay, Webster, Lawrence, and other
nationalists, a federal bank did far
more than this. A national bank's loans and
discounts, though local, were a source
of much needed capital. Loans not only
affected the currency, which Tyler
denied, but also influenced economic stability and
growth. Because most loans, especially
in the West, were made in the form of
currency rather than demand deposits,
they increased the circulating medium in
general and uniform circulation in
particular. When the bank's large capital was
lent, the economy expanded; when
withdrawn, it contracted. In short, the bank's
ability to finance economic growth, as
envisioned by the Ewing and Clay bills, was
completely overlooked by Tyler.
Finally, obeying his states rights
dictates, the President found that the sovereign
rights of the states were still not
sufficiently secured in the bill. This last objection
was perhaps the crucial part of the
message and surely the principal factor in Tyler's
decision. The nationalists, in
contravention, held that Congress had such power and
had composed the branching provisions as
a concession to the President.48
The moderate Whigs still hoped for a
settlement after the veto. Virginia Repre-
sentative Alexander H. Stuart went to
Tyler with a modification of Senator Bayard's
defeated amendment. The new provision
would forbid the conversion of agencies
into branches but would permit the
establishment of agencies without state assent.
Tyler seemed to accept this basic
concept. The Whig caucus instructed John Sergeant
and Senator John Berrien to draw up a
bill on this scheme and seek an interview
with the President to insure that there
was no misunderstanding.
At the Cabinet meeting on August 18, the
President was informed that Congress
was perfectly ready now to pass Ewing's
bill. Tyler replied: "Talk not to me of Mr.
Ewing's Bill--it contains that odious
feature of local discounts which I have re-
pudiated in my message." According
to Ewing's diary, Ewing then asked Tyler to
state his opinions so that there would
be no misunderstanding among the Cabinet.
Tyler said he desired a bank of issue
and deposit with power to deal in bills of ex-
change without state assent but not to
discount promissory notes. Ewing and Webster
at the President's urging helped to draw
up the new bill according to his wishes. While
the bill was under consideration in
Congress, the President more than once stated
to his Secretary of the Treasury that he
desired a postponement and gave strong
intimations that he would veto any bank
bill. Ewing personally attempted to have the
48. Tappan Senate Journal, August 6, 9,
15, 16, 1841; Francis P. Weisenburger, The Passing
of the Frontier, 1825-1850 (Carl Wittke, ed., History of the State of Ohio, III, Columbus,
1941),
399; Richardson, Papers of the
Presidents, IV, 63-68; Congressional Globe, 27 Cong., 1 Sess.,
Appendix, 365.
22 OHIO
HISTORY
bill postponed, but he was unsuccessful.
He sensed that Clay was "hurrying matters
to a catastrophe," that is, force
another veto, "compel the Cabinet to resign...
denounce the Administration and make
himself as the head of the Whig party an
opposition candidate for the
Presidency."49
The new bill, first introduced into the
House by Sergeant, was modeled on the
Clay, or vetoed bill, but contained
three major alterations. The capital of the bank
was reduced to $21,000,000 with power to
increase it to $35,000,000. There were
to be no offices of discount and
deposit, only agencies. The bank's operations were
to be confined to buying and selling
foreign bills of exchange, including those drawn
in one state and payable in another.
There were to be no discounts, and all references
to them were struck out of the bill. The
bill passed the House in two days after little
debate. Ohio's delegation voted as
before along strict party lines. The moderate
Whigs sincerely believed the bill to be
what the President wanted. Tyler, however,
confided to Tappan on August 18 that he
believed the Whigs "were trying to deceive
him into signing another bank bill with
a view to destroy his character entirely."
Later he spoke to Tappan with much
contempt for the bank bill as it had passed
the House and stated that "the more
ridiculous they [Congress] made it the easier
it would be for him to veto it."50
Berrien introduced the bill in the
Senate despite Tappan's plea for a postponement.
Clay made a conciliatory speech
accepting what were now the minimum Whig de-
mands. The debate was a battle over the
exchange provisions. Tappan led the
Democrats who insisted that the exchange
transactions were actually authorized
discounts. The ability to deal in bills
drawn in one state and payable in another
sanctioned a mode of discounting paper
and making loans common in the West. The
western banks found it far more
profitable to deal in exchange and few directly
discounted promissory notes. Tappan
charged the title should read "The United
States Bank." Whigs denied the
charges, the power of local discounts being expressly
expunged. Rives claimed that the only
power that would satisfy Tyler was exchange
dealings limited to cash drafts payable
on demand. The bill passed on a strictly
party vote.51
At the President's request Ewing again
prepared an argument explaining the
constitutionality of the bill and
demonstrating that a national bank was a necessary
and proper means of answering the
Government's fiscal needs. He pointed out how
a bank dealing in exchanges would aid
the country. If the bank used its capital
solely for exchanges, it set free bank
capital so applied, and directed the money
towards financing economic growth.52
After its passage, Tyler claimed he
never saw the bill before it was submitted to
Congress. Webster claimed that to his
knowledge Tyler had read the bill and
personally had written down his changes.
On September 9, Tyler vetoed the bill,
again objecting to a bank which was
national in character. The greater part of the
veto criticized the exchange provisions.
Local discounts could occur under the guise
49. Chitwood, John Tyler, 238-242,
247-248, 264, 469-470; "Ewing Diary," 99-106.
50. H.R. 14 and S. 5, Bills and
Resolutions Originated in the House of Representatives, 1841,
File 27, A-B 1; Original Engrossed
Bills, 27 Cong., Vol. 7, Record Group 233, National Archives;
Congressional Globe, 27 Cong., 1 Sess., 363-372; Tappan Senate Journal,
August 18, 23, 1841.
51. Congressional Globe, 27
Cong., 1 Sess., 372, 378-379, 402, 418-423, Appendix, 337-350.
The vote in the Senate: 27-22; House:
125-94.
52. Ewing to His Excellency the
President of the United States, late August 1841, Vol. 6,
Ewing Papers.
Thomas Ewing 23
of bills of exchange--such as a
Cincinnati bill drawn on a bank in a Kentucky
border town. Tyler apparently was
confused on fiscal matters and persisted in using
the words "local discount" in
the general sense of local loans.53 The nationalists,
who were now willing to forego the power
of local loans in order to establish a
national bank that would achieve the
minimum Whig goal--a uniform currency
and bills of exchange to economically
move the country's goods and finance eco-
nomic growth--were again defeated.
Samson Mason, one of Ohio's Whig
Congressmen, delivered a long speech against
the veto. Tyler had failed to fulfill
the pledges he had made to provide the nation
with a uniform currency, even after
Congress had made concessions to the President
regarding the branching power. Mourned
John Q. Adams, "We all felt that the
hour for the requiem of the Whig party
was at hand."54
On September 11 the Cabinet resigned.
Ewing had earlier considered the problem
of being forced to leave and had
conferred with Congressmen Patrick Goode and
Samuel Stokely and Alfred Kelley who
felt he should remain until removed by the
President, but the veto changed Ewing's
mind. Webster asked Ewing to reconsider
his decision to resign immediately. The
Secretary of the Treasury, however, felt he
could not stay and maintain his
reputation for truth. His letter of resignation pointed
out the inexplicable inconsistency in
the President's objections to those very provi-
sions which were inserted at his
request. "I cannot abandon the principles for which,
during all my public career, I have
struggled. ... "55
The failure to establish a national bank
was deeply felt in Ohio. The esteemed
paper, Niles' Register, stated:
"There is no state in the Union in which at present
the subject of banks and banking is more
agitated, on [sic] or where wise legislation
to obviate the difficulties they are
laboring under is more required."56 The state
banking system became the center of a
political storm for a decade and was reduced
to inadequacy, resulting in an unstable
currency and a lack of capital which affected
the rate of economic growth. Governor
Tom Corwin requested the Assembly to act,
pointing out that banks were still
failing in the wake of the depression and the
charters of nearly all the Ohio banks
would expire in January 1843, causing the
withdrawal of a great deal of capital
from the state. The interests of the people
demanded the retention of well-regulated
banking.
The antibank, hard-money radical
Democrats won control of the state in 1841
and 1842 and refused to recharter the
existing banks. Instead they shrewdly agreed
to the passage of a general banking law,
the Latham Act, which provided for such
rigid regulations that it was hoped
their goal, the destruction of all banks, would
be achieved, for no banks were organized
under it. The amendments of 1843
proved no more successful. Ohio was thus
forced to rely upon neighboring states
and unauthorized banking institutions
for circulation. Banks or no banks was again
a major issue in the fall election of
1843. The Whigs won control of the legislature
and were faced with drafting an entirely
new banking system. Only eight authorized
banks remained in 1844, with a capital
of $2,304,745. Loans and discounts had
53. Tyler, Letters of the Tylers, II, 86, 98;
Chitwood, John Tyler, 261; Richardson, Papers of
the Presidents, IV, 68-72.
54. Congressional Globe, 27 Cong., 1 Sess., 450, Appendix, 393; Adams, John
Q. Adams,
XI, 14.
55. "Ewing Diary," 106-107;
Ewing to Clay, November 1, 1843, Vol. 23, Clay Papers; Letters
of Resignation, Niles' Register, LXI
(September 18, 1841), 32-34.
56. Ibid., LXV (December 16, 1843), 243.
24 OHIO
HISTORY
reached their nadir, under $3,000,000;
and circulation was $2,200,000, just about
the 1833 level.
The Whigs determined to respond to
public complaints of the scarcity of money
and inadequate banking facilities. In
1845 Alfred Kelley's bill, based on the best
experience of other states, provided for
organizing two new classes of banks in
addition to the retention of the
existing banks. The State Bank of Ohio with power
to branch was one, and independent
banks, the other. The number of banks in the
twelve designated districts was to be
limited, and a bond secured, uniform and
redeemable circulation and many safety
precautions were included. This legislation
made Ohio's banking system one of the
best in the nation prior to the Civil War.
Five years later the hard-money
Democrats were defeated in their attempts to
prohibit banks in the new state
constitution, and the long and bitter controversy
slowly ended on the state level. Difficulties
in Ohio's banking system and an unstable
currency nationally that increased the
costs for businesses and individuals could
have been avoided had Thomas Ewing's
bill been enacted. Developments proved
the veracity of the Whig position that
banks and the process of controlled credit
creation were essential to orderly
economic growth, but what is remarkable is that
the hard-money advocates with their
inadequate views of economic development
almost won nationally as well as in
Ohio.57
History, thus, seems to have been on the
side of the Whigs. Sincerely believing
in the constitutional power of the
Federal Government to give positive assistance in
the economic development of the country
and nationalist in outlook, the party had
strived for an adequate national
currency and a bank to stimulate and regulate
economic growth. Thomas Ewing perceived
the inability of any one state, no matter
how efficient its banking system, to
provide the nation with a stable monetary sys-
tem. The Whigs' failure to solve the
major issue of the times in 1832 and 1841
continued to have important
repercussions on the financial history and banking
structure of the United States as the
nation developed industrially and increased its
influence in international affairs. The
nation would have benefitted in the long-run
had there been a national institution to
temper the rapidity and direction of economic
growth. With a national bank, western
settlement and development would have
occurred at a more even pace. The
various state banking systems were instrumental
in transforming the primitive
agricultural economy of the nation into a more sophis-
ticated and highly productive one. But
the Whig idea for a national bank would have
reached the same end by means of more
orderly economic growth.58
57. Huntington, "History of Banking
in Ohio," 396-399, 403-408, 413-428, 446, 481-484;
Golembe, "State Banks," 201,
238-240; Sharp, Jacksonians Versus the Banks, 15-16, 124, 133-
159, 188-189, 194-195; Trescott, Financing
American Enterprise, 39-40.
58. It was not until December 1913,
seventy-two years after Tyler's veto of the Third Na-
tional Bank charter, that a central
banking system was finally established by the Federal
Reserve Act, assuring an elastic
currency and central control over the nation's credit supply.