THOMAS S. MACH
George Hunt Pendleton, The Ohio Idea
and Political Continuity in Reconstruction
America
The severe defeat of the Democrats in
the 1866 election in Ohio and across
the country left some of the party's
political positions meaningless. With a
Republican majority in Congress and
Reconstruction issues under its control,
the Democratic Party pinned its future
on the ideas of a politician in the
throes of resurrecting a political
career. George Hunt Pendleton, a leading
Democrat from Ohio, had made a name for
himself during the Civil War as a
Peace Democrat representing southwestern
Ohio in Congress. He had run
with General George McClellan in 1864
for the vice-presidency, but with the
war won and the Republicans waving the
bloody shirt, Pendleton seemed des-
tined for obscurity. Following the war,
the Democrats were adrift in terms of
policies, issues and leaders. They had
supported President Johnson, but his
growing unpopularity and unwillingness
to cooperate with them promised
years of campaign defeats. The Democrats
continued to show a lack of imag-
ination in 1866 when they campaigned in
opposition to Congressional
Reconstruction. 1
Pendleton initially was no different
from other Democrats; he followed the
same obstructionist policies and lost
his 1866 bid for Congress. But
Pendleton realized this approach,
however much sense it made in the short
run, was an expedient that failed to
rebuild the southern Democracy, did not
restore the prewar party's sectional
alignments, and lent credence to
Republican attacks that the Democrats
had flirted with treason during the war.
Thomas S. Mach is an Associate Professor
of History at Mount Vernon Nazarene
College in Mount Vernon, Ohio. The
author would like to thank Professor Jerome
Mushkat for his steadfast encouragement
and helpful comments in the completion
of this article.
1. Eric L. McKitrick, Andrew Johnson
and Reconstruction (Chicago, 1960),
274-325; Robert D. Sawrey, Dubious
Victor: The Reconstruction Debate in Ohio
(Lexington, Ky., 1992), 59-67; W. R.
Brock, An American Crisis: Congress and
Reconstruction, 1865-1867 (London, 1963), 105-22; Floyd O. Rittenhouse,
"George Hunt Pendleton: With
Special Reference to His Congressional Career"
(Master's thesis, The Ohio State University,
1932), 53-55; Clifford H. Moore,
"Ohio in National Politics,
1865-1896," Ohio Archaeological and Historical
Society Publications, 37 (April, 1928), 236-40.
126 OHIO HISTORY
Pendleton had the imagination and drive
to propose a new direction through
his sponsorship of the Ohio Idea, also
known as the Pendleton Plan. More
than an irresponsible monetarist effort
to inflate the currency or harm the na-
tion's credit rating on bonded
indebtedness, as critics charged, Pendleton pro-
posed the Ohio Idea to settle lingering
wartime issues and to refashion the
Democracy by reviving its Jacksonian
heritage. The success of such an ef-
fort, Pendleton assumed, would move the
party away from the dead past, ad-
dress new issues popular with voters,
and gain the presidential nomination for
himself in 1868. Yet Pendleton faced a
difficult task. The Democracy was
rife with competing regional interests
and leaders, many of whom for their
own self-interests were more concerned
with gaining power as an end in itself
than in setting a fresh course for the
future.
A study of Pendleton's Ohio Idea has
dimensions beyond a simple narrative
of Ohio and national politics, or his
failed bid for the presidency. In one
sense, the internal debate within the
Democracy over the Ohio Idea reveals the
continuing divisions among Democrats and
their unwillingness to accept
Pendleton's revised interpretation of
Jacksonianism in the postwar era. But in
a larger way, this study indicates a
basic continuity that existed between both
Democrats and Republicans. An analysis of the currency question that
Pendleton posed in the Ohio Idea shows
that the two major political parties,
led by many of the same men who had
dominated partisanship before the war,
debated issues-albeit new ones-within
the rhetorical and ideological param-
eters common in antebellum America. In
short, an examination of the Ohio
Idea reveals that the Civil War did not
destroy the prewar political system, but
rather continued its basic character. As
a result, Pendleton's efforts illustrated
the continuity, not change, that
determined partisanship in the postwar period.
The Jacksonian Roots of the Ohio Idea
In 1866, both the Midwest and the South
were undergoing severe financial
collapse brought on partly by the
devastation of the Civil War and two years
of poor harvests, and partly by the
Republican policy of deflationary contrac-
tion of the currency. Republicans had
created a National Bank System during
the war to provide a mechanism for
promoting uniformity of currency and for
selling government bonds. National banks
bought bonds and were granted the
privilege of issuing a limited amount of
banknotes in return. The govern-
ment also began issuing greenbacks as an
additional means of financing the
war. Following the war, Secretary of the
Treasury Hugh McCulloch began
rapidly removing those greenbacks from
the currency in an effort to return to
specie payments.2
2. Michael Les Benedict, A Compromise
of Principle: Congressional
George Hunt Pendleton 127
Pendleton had opposed both of the
initial measures. Consistent with his
party's Jacksonian heritage, he neither
wanted to see the national government
gain greater power nor to watch capital
become increasingly concentrated in
the Northeast portion of the country.
Traditionally, Jacksonian Democrats
had opposed a National Bank System on
the basis of both of those concerns
and sought a more equitable distribution
of capital throughout the country.
To bring change, Pendleton needed to
devise a means to make currency more
accessible in the southern and
midwestern economies. While a share of
National bank charters were designated
for these regions, the Department of
the Treasury, during the war years,
allowed New England and New York City
to claim most of the charters. Most
likely it was convenient for Washington
to have the system regionalized as funds
were sought for the war effort. In
addition, the South forfeited potential
branches during secession. Following
the war, southerners sought ways to keep
currency in their section because
Republican economic policies did not
provide for their financial needs. Money
that went South chasing cotton and other
agricultural crops stayed there as
southern farmers diversified to meet
their own needs for foodstuffs and eco-
nomic recovery. The result of the lack
of capital and the southern attempt at
self-sufficiency was a declining demand
for midwestern farm goods.
Pendleton hoped to alleviate the plight
of both sections while rebuilding his
party.3
The money question aroused a host of
financial and political issues. In
their April 1867 convention, the State
Sovereignty Democrats, an extreme
states' rights group which later
encouraged Kentucky to nullify Congressional
Reconstruction legislation, launched the
debate. The organization, led by
Henry Clay Dean and Alexander Long,
believed that the Democratic Party had
disowned its principles, and they
threatened to form a movement calling for
Republicans and Reconstruction,
1863-1869, (New York, 1974), 262-64;
Max L.
Shipley, "The Background and Legal
Aspects of the Pendleton Plan," Mississippi
Valley Historical Review, 24 (September, 1937), 329-32; Chester M. Destler,
American Radicalism, 1865-1901:
Essays and Documents, (New York,
1963), 32-
34; Robert P. Sharkey, Money, Class,
and Party: An Economic Study of the Civil
War and Reconstruction, (Baltimore, 1959), 56-80.
3. George H. Pendleton, Payment of
the Public Debt in Legal Tender Notes!!
Speech of Hon. George H. Pendleton,
Milwaukee, November 2, 1867 (n.p.,
n.d.),
11-12; George H. Pendleton, "Speech
of Hon. George H. Pendleton, of Ohio, at
Grafton, West Virginia, July 16,
1868," in Democratic Speaker's Handbook
(Cincinnati, 1868), 310-15; Cincinnati
Enquirer, July 22, 1867; Shipley,
"Background of the Pendleton
Plan," 329-32; Destler, American Radicalism, 32-
34; Sharkey, Money, Class, and Party,
56-80; George L. Anderson, "The South
and Problems of Post-Civil War
Finance," Journal of Southern History, 9 (August,
1943), 181-95; Albert V. House,
"Northern Congressional Democrats as
Defenders of the South During
Reconstruction," Journal of Southern History, 6
(February, 1940), 46-48.
128 OHIO HISTORY
total repudiation of the national debt.
In June, Washington McLean of the
Cincinnati Enquirer tempered the proposal by suggesting that the United
States pay the entire federal debt in
greenbacks. Traditional hard-money
Democrats rejected that sweeping
proposal, believing that dramatic inflation
would result. Long, Dean, and McLean,
all former Peace Democrats, were re-
sponding to the cries of midwestern
farmers who believed contraction of
greenbacks would cause crop prices to
fall, making it more difficult to pay off
their debts.4
Hugh J. Jewett, a prominent Ohio
Democrat, fearing the extreme nature of
both plans, suggested a conservative
alternative that offered bondholders the
choice between repayment in greenbacks
or an exchange of their bonds for
taxable securities bearing lower
interest rates. Jewett further suggested that
greenbacks replace national banknotes
which were secured by government
bonds. The process included withdrawing
the banknotes and buying the bonds
back with greenbacks which could then be
put in circulation to replace the
notes. The plan provided multiple
blessings for midwestern Democrats.
First, it would save the government
millions in interest currently being paid
on the bonds. Second, it would maintain
currency levels in their section,
preventing crop prices from falling and
interest rates from rising too steeply.
The government could then put the income
from taxes and savings from
lower interest payments into a sinking
fund to pay the outstanding bonds as
they matured.5
McLean recognized that these conflicting
and often confusing plans were
beyond the understanding of most
ordinary voters. Under these circumstances,
he sought an articulate spokesman;
Pendleton seemed the logical choice.
During his congressional terms,
Pendleton had established a solid reputation
on finance and financial matters.
Equally vital, Pendleton continued at the
forefront of Ohio Democratic politics
despite his 1866 loss. Nothing better
illustrated his position than his
selection as president of the Democratic State
Convention in January 1867, which he
controlled along with Clement L.
Vallandigham and Allen G. Thurman. But
Pendleton was not yet ready to as-
sume the role McLean desired for him.
Rather, Pendleton still hammered at
Congressional Reconstruction.6
4. Destler, American Radicalism, 49;
Robert D. Sawrey, Dubious Victor: The
Reconstruction Debate in Ohio (Lexington, Ky., 1992), 107-09; Don C. Barrett,
The Greenbacks and Resumption of
Specie Payments, 1862-1879, Harvard
Economic Studies, vol. 36 (Cambridge,
Mass., 1931), 161-69.
5. Destler, American Radicalism, 37-38;
Sharkey, Money, Class, and Party, 98-
101; Cincinnati Enquirer, Apr.
19, June 6, 1867; Eugene H. Roseboom, The Civil
War Era, 1850-1873, vol. 4 of The History of the State of Ohio (Columbus,
Ohio,
1944), 459.
6. George H. Porter, Ohio Politics
During the Civil War Period, Columbia
University Studies in the Social Science
(1911; reprint, New York, 1968), 238-
George Hunt Pendleton 129 |
|
The campaign began with no references to debt payment and Pendleton did not mention debt reduction in his public speeches as late as April 1867. Instead he continued to attack Congressional Reconstruction and the Fourteenth Amendment, contending they trampled on state sovereignty. By the summer, however, Pendleton began to develop his own scheme for eradi- cating the public debt and the evils of the country's financial system. After some cajoling by McLean, Pendleton began to strike out alone, asking the party faithful to support him rather than letting others formulate a Democratic monetary policy. Yet the form his plan took was not as extreme as McLean had wanted. The issue on which Pendleton staked his political future was the payment of a portion of the Civil War debt in greenbacks.7 Pendleton used the 1867 campaign to initiate a year and a half of travel with the dual purposes of restructuring the Democratic Party and building support for a presidential bid in 1868. The debt issue became the theme for
43; Roseboom, Civil War Era, 459; Cincinnati Enquirer, Jan. 9, 10, May 8, Sept. 18, 1867; New York Times, Jan. 9, 13, 1867. 7. Cincinnati Enquirer, April 26, May 3, 1867; New York Times, April 29, 1867; John H. James, Jr. to Pendleton, Feb. 31, March 29, April 15, 1867, James Family Papers, Ohio Historical Society, Columbus. |
130 OHIO HISTORY
this effort. He first addressed the
public debt issue in Minnesota on July 11,
1867. Jewett had given his speech just
six days before, but it was not printed
in Cincinnati newspapers until after
Pendleton returned from Minnesota.
Whether he had knowledge of the Jewett
plan is unclear, but what is clear is
that Pendleton was thinking along
similar lines. Pendleton condemned the
federal policy that allowed bondholders
to purchase the securities in depreci-
ated currency, receive 6 percent
interest in gold, and pay no taxes on the in-
come. Meanwhile, agrarian and trades
workers, who could not afford such in-
vestment, struggled under the combined
weight of heavy debt loads and high
taxes to pay the excessive interest
rate. National banks held a sizable portion
of these bonds as collateral for the
issuance of banknotes, thus enhancing
their economic power. The Ohio
legislature had expressed similar outrage in
1866 when it called for state taxation
of national securities. Bank owners not
only received 6 percent interest on the
bonds, but also gained the right to loan
banknotes at rates of 6, 8 or even 15
percent. Pendleton decried this system:
The manifest interest of the people is,
that these bonds be redeemed in legal tender
notes. The interest on these bonds would
thus be saved, and the currency, if any be
needed, would thus be furnished free of
cost to the people.8
Pendleton began to specify the
provisions of his plan, while carefully dis-
sociating himself from McLean's
inflationary notions, in a speech in Lima,
Ohio.
The total debt, Pendleton said, amounted to $2.2 billion, with
$140,000,000 in interest paid yearly.
Half of the debt was in five to twenty-
year bonds, callable after five years
and yielding an interest rate of 6 percent
yearly. Pendleton limited his proposal
for paying the debt in greenbacks to
these bonds, because purchasers bought
them with legal tender and no contrac-
tual stipulation existed regarding their
payment. The national banks held
$400,000,000 of these bonds, which
Pendleton asserted could be called in at
an annual savings to the government of
$24,000,000 in interest payments
without causing inflation. He maintained
that the interest saved could be
added to a portion of existing tax
revenues and used to create a sinking fund to
pay off the rest of the federal debt
over a period of sixteen years. To succeed,
the plan not only required the momentary
continuation of high taxes, but also
the reduction of federal spending. The
plan would not cause overt inflation of
prices because as bank-held bonds were
redeemed, bankers would no longer
8. Cincinnati Enquirer, July 17,
1867; Destler, American Radicalism, 38-39;
New York Times, July 17, 1867; Taxing National Currency, Etc. (16
April 1866),
39th Cong., 1st sess., H. Miscellaneous
Document 87, (Serial 1271); Letter of the
Secretary of the Treasury to the
Chairman of the Committee on Finance,
Transmitting a Statement Relative to
the Apportionment of National Currency (23
April 1866), 39th Cong., 1st sess., S.
Miscellaneous Document 100, (Serial
1239); Government Funds in National
Banks (9 January 1868), 40th Cong., 2nd
sess., H. Executive Document 87, (Serial
1332).
George Hunt Pendleton 131
have the required collateral to issue
banknotes. In essence, the greenbacks
would replace the banknotes.
Nonetheless, Pendleton contended that some
currency inflation was desirable to make
capital more available for rebuilding
the South and reviving an economy in
recession. He could assure the country
an end to war taxes after a specified
time period while providing the necessary
capital for southern agricultural needs
and the nation's growing industrial con-
cerns. After all, the gains of paying
off the debt, he argued, outweighed any
possible detriment caused by limited
price inflation.9
In Milwaukee two weeks later, Pendleton
contended that his idea would
limit inflation by stabilizing the
greenback's value at approximately 71 cents
in gold per dollar as legal tender. The
gold in the sinking fund would be con-
verted to greenbacks to redeem the
five-twenties when they matured. After
they were retired, the government could
gradually lower taxes by
$150,000,000 and still have enough
available in 1874 to pay off the gold
bonds. Taxes could again be reduced
after 1874, allowing for gradual with-
drawal of the greenbacks. Pendleton
estimated that by 1881 the nation could
retire its debt and return to specie
payments. Pendleton asserted that by the
time his plan achieved it goals, the
Republican method would have paid little
more than the annual interest on the
debt.10 In fifteen years, accumulated
in-
terest would double the debt, while
Republican contraction schemes reduced
the economic base from which taxes were
gathered.11
9.
Pendleton argued that the Republican contraction program
would add
$48,000,000 in yearly interest payments.
George H. Pendleton, Speech of Hon.
George H. Pendleton, Delivered at
Lima, Allen County, Ohio, Thursday, August
15, 1867 (Columbus: The Crisis Office, 1867), 4-5; Extracts
from Hon. George H.
Pendleton's Speeches at Lima and
Cleveland (n.p., n.d.), 2-4; Cincinnati
Enquirer,
Aug. 16, 1867; New York Times, Aug.
18, 1867; Moore, "Ohio in National
Politics," 250; Benedict, A
Compromise of Principle, 262-63. Destler suggests
that Pendleton adopted Jewett's sinking
fund idea. Destler, American Radicalism,
39; Pendleton's figures were rounded off
estimates, but were reasonably accurate.
Statement of the Public Debt of the
United States (3 March 1868), 40th
Cong.,
2nd sess., H. Misdoc. 87, (Serial 1350).
10. Pendleton, Payment of the Public
Debt, 1-12; Cincinnati Enquirer, Nov. 7,
1867; Destler, American Radicalism, 39-41.
11. The Times reluctantly
accepted the correction of a subscriber that Pendleton
was being misrepresented in the paper.
While the paper acknowledged that
Pendleton was not the inflationist that
others were, it doubted whether his plan
could be accomplished without some
inflation. New York Times, Nov. 18, 1867.
Pendleton wrote to Manton Marble of the New
York World hoping he would print a
portion of his Milwaukee speech to
respond to the Times. Marble was cordial to
Pendleton and complied with his request,
but was not a supporter of the plan.
Nonetheless, Marble defended Pendleton
from critics who called him an inflation-
ist. Pendleton to Marble, Nov. 13, 1867,
Marble to Pendleton, Nov. 23, 1867,
Manton Marble Papers, Manuscripts
Division, Library of Congress, Washington,
DC; New York World, Nov. 19,
1867, Feb. 1, 4, May 6, 29, 1868; Pendleton to
Horace Greeley, Nov. 13, 1867, Horace
Greeley Papers, Manuscript Division,
132 OHIO HISTORY
Pendleton also addressed questions of
personal inconsistency about his vote
against the Legal Tender Act in 1862.
Congressional Democrats, who had
almost unanimously joined Pendleton
then, remained consistent on this issue
until 1866 when they supported
McCulloch's monetary contraction program.
Within two years, however, most of them
voted to end contraction. The ex-
planation for this reversal, and Pendleton's
apparent contradiction, supplies
some insight into the party's reversals.
Pendleton initially deemed green-
backs to be an evil, but because the
government considered fiat adequate for
the soldier, he believed the same
standard ought also to apply to the five-
twenty bondholder. Moreover,
manufacturers and laborers in the Midwest
valued greenbacks as the key to
prosperity in the postwar recession. Yet they
also viewed bondholders and bankers as
the reason for much of their financial
trouble, and saw no reason for them to
have favored status in the eyes of the
government. While Pendleton's goal was
the resumption of specie, he could
find no reason to scorn the utility of
greenbacks to make that transition as
painless as possible.12
There were several threads of continuity
within his otherwise seemingly
contradictory position. Pendleton had long opposed the National Bank
System. Based on his Jacksonian roots,
he thought that the National Banks
prevented the Midwest from achieving its
economic potential. Pendleton
played on the midwestern complaint,
latent since the days of Jackson's war on
the Second Bank of the United States,
that the East monopolized the coun-
try's capital. In addition, Pendleton
tried to appeal to a broad constituency by
using Jacksonian methods. His own
support base, largely Ohio farmers, tra-
ditionally voted Democratic and blamed
Republican financial policies for their
current financial woes. Too, Pendleton
attempted to appeal to eastern labor-
ers, much the same way that Jackson had,
on the basis of class conflict.
Pendleton railed against the privilege
and special status Republicans afforded
to bondholders, reminiscent of Jackson's
attack on Nicholas Biddle and eastern
banks. Pendleton capped his argument by
returning to Jackson's governmen-
tal philosophy. Pendleton disdained the
existing financial system as an auxil-
iary part of the plan of national
consolidation which the Republican leviathan
state had created during the war.
Through monetary contraction and the main-
tenance of the National Bank System, he
further reasoned, eastern Republican
financiers kept the southern states
under their thumb. In the end, Pendleton's
goals remained the same even if his
methods changed. His plan would de-
stroy the National Bank System and help
thwart the Republican power
grab.13
Library of Congress, Washington, DC;
Destler, American Radicalism, 40-41.
12. Pendleton, Payment of the Public
Debt, 9; Edward McPherson, A Handbook
of Politics for 1868 (1868; reprint, New York, 1969), 354.
13. Ibid.; Pendleton, Payment of the
Public Debt, 9; While Sharkey and Sawrey
George Hunt Pendleton 133
Pendleton's Presidential Bid
The fall elections gave Pendleton a
boost in his marathon effort to employ
the developing Pendleton Plan as the
road to the White House. The results in
Ohio, a pleasant surprise for the
Democrats, came about only through strenu-
ous efforts; Pendleton alone had visited
thirty counties in less than two
months. The Republicans did very poorly,
in spite of the fact that Rutherford
B. Hayes won the gubernatorial election.
The Democrats gained a majority in
the Ohio legislature, which meant
Benjamin Wade, a leading Radical
Republican, forfeited his seat in the
United States Senate. In addition, Ohio
voters overwhelmingly rejected the
Fourteenth Amendment. While
Democratic gains in Ohio resulted
largely from the widespread use of pure
racism and the opposition to black
suffrage, rising support for Pendleton's
debt payment plan played a role as
well.14 The 1867 election represented a
tend to dismiss Pendleton's ideas as
politically expedient and philosophically in-
consistent with Jacksonianism, other
historians disagree. One of the earliest to
note Pendleton's focus on special
privilege was Max Shipley. Chester M. Destler
followed Shipley's work, calling
Pendleton "at the worst, ... a re-inflationist."
Irwin Unger echoes Destler's comments
noting that while hard-money Democrats
accused Pendleton of inconsistency,
their charges that he was an inflationist were
"unfair." One of the most
recent studies of the era concurs that Pendleton was es-
sentially consistent to long-held
Jacksonian ideals. Gretchen Ritter notes that
under the Pendleton Plan, Jacksonian
principle was reinterpreted to advocate paper
money while maintaining the traditional
opposition to the banking system and
special status for bondholders. Yet none
of these historians takes a strong enough
stand on the basic consistency of
Pendleton's plan with Jacksonianism.
Even
Ritter, who speaks the most forthrightly
in her comparison of the plan with
Jacksonian ideas, classifies Pendleton
as an antimonopolist rather than a conser-
vative. She places Jacksonianism within
her "conservative" category but not the
Pendleton Plan, because she fails to
emphasize Pendleton's ultimate goal of specie
resumption. Sharkey, Money, Class,
and Party, 99-107, 197, 219, 282-85;
Shipley, "Background of the
Pendleton Plan," 339; Destler, American Radicalism,
40; Irwin Unger, The Greenback Era: A
Social and Political History of American
Finance, 1865-1879 (Princeton, N.J., 1964), 84; Gretchen Ritter, Goldbugs
and
Greenbacks: The Antimonopoly
Tradition and the Politics of Finance in America
(New York, 1997), 1-9, 41-44; Charles H.
Coleman, The Election of 1868: The
Democratic Effort to Regain Control, (New York, 1971), 25-33; Cincinnati
Enquirer, Feb. 5, 1868; Benjamin E. Green to Samuel J. Randall,
Jan. 2, 1868,
Samuel J. Randall Papers, University of
Pennsylvania Library, Philadelphia;
Joseph Medill to Sherman, Jan. 7, 1868,
John Sherman Papers, Manuscript
Division, Library of Congress,
Washington, D.C.
14. Destler, Unger and Benedict
emphasize the importance of the currency issue
while Jerome Mushkat and Sawrey point to
race issues. Benedict noted, "In Ohio
the money question had damaged
Republicans." Benedict, A Compromise of
Principle, 273; Destler, American Radicalism, 32-40; Unger,
The Greenback Era,
80-87; Jerome Mushkat, The
Reconstruction of the New York Democracy, 1861-
1874 (East Brunswick, N.J., 1981), 113-20; Sawrey, Dubious
Victory, 105-07.
134 OHIO HISTORY
very early success in the process of
educating the party on Pendleton's finan-
cial ideas. Writing of the party's
bright future to New Yorker Horatio
Seymour, Pendleton said, "Our labor
will just have begun for there comes the
question of administering the power
which will be confided to our hands."15
Pendleton's plan engendered considerable
debate throughout the nation. At
first, both major parties in Cincinnati,
represented by the Commercial and the
Enquirer, endorsed the payment of five-twenties in
greenbacks. Ohio
Republican John Sherman asserted that
the idea was legal.16 Some leading
Radical Republicans such as Thaddeus
Stevens and Benjamin Bannan pro-
posed similar ideas. The Radical Daily
Gazette supported the idea for a time.
The Democratic Enquirer, however,
advocated an increase in the number of
greenbacks in circulation to accomplish
the goal. Yet the 1867 election re-
sults and the growing midwestern support
for Pendleton and his plan caused
the Republicans great consternation and
forced them to reassess their initial
approval. Some began to counsel adoption
of the payment plan, while others
suggested initiating a federal tax on
the bonds to placate those who thought
bondholders had become a privileged
class. Joseph Medill, editor of the
Republican Chicago Tribune, warned
John Sherman that the Republican
Party could no longer rely on
Reconstruction issues to win elections. In or-
der to maintain power, Medill suggested,
the Republicans needed to placate
midwesterners on financial issues.17
15. New York Leader, Oct. 12,
1867; New York World, Oct. 14, 1867; New York
Tribune, Oct. 14, 1867; New York Herald, Oct. 7, 9, 10,
12, 1867; Boston Daily
Courier, Oct. 11, 17, 18, 1867; Cincinnati Enquirer, Oct.
2, 1867; Pendleton to
Horatio Seymour, Oct. 21, 1867,
Fairchild Collection, New York Historical
Society, New York. A Sherman
correspondent noted that the currency question had
eclipsed the amendment issue by the time
of the election. J. C. Devin to John
Sherman, Sept. 30, 1867, Schuyler Colfax
to Sherman, Oct. 12, 1867, Sherman
Papers; McPherson, Handbook of
Politics for 1868, 354-55; Porter, Ohio
Politics, 235-48; Roseboom, Civil War Era, 457-63; Moore,
"Ohio in National
Politics," 240-44.
16. New York Times, Sept. 22,
1867; John Sherman, Funding of the National
Debt, Speech of Hon. John Sherman, of
Ohio, in the United States Senate, May
22, 1866 (n.p., n.d.), 1-15; Sherman later recanted, saying he
had not favored the
payment of the debt in greenbacks until
they were at par with gold, which he said
was stipulated in the original legal
tender act. In essence, the bonds were payable
in greenbacks, but only when they were
at par. John Sherman, John Sherman's
Recollections of Forty Years in the
House, Senate and Cabinet. An
Autobiography, vol. 2 (Chicago, 1895), 624-25.
17.
Destler, American Radicalism, 34-35; Shipley, "Background of
the
Pendleton Plan," 330-35; Sharkey, Money,
Class, and Party, 96-97; David
Montgomery, Beyond Equality: Labor
and the Radical Republicans, 1862-1872,
(Chicago, 1981), 340-56; R. J. to
Sherman, Nov. 11, 1867, Joseph Medill to
Sherman, Nov. 22, 1867, Jan. 7, 1868,
David Wilder to Sherman, Dec. 20, 1867,
C. Davenport to Sherman, Dec. 27, 1867,
Sherman Papers; Samuel S. Cox to
Marble, Oct. 1, 1867, Marble Papers; New
York Leader, Aug. 24, 1867;
George Hunt Pendleton 135
Some Republicans may have seen in the
currency issue a repose from the
dangerous issues associated with
Congressional Reconstruction. Indeed, this
popular midwestern question could be a
political knife to deflate a Democracy
swelling from the agitation over black
suffrage. For the Republicans, how-
ever, this knife would turn into a
two-edged sword. They had their own divi-
sions as Radicals attempted to maintain
their power in the party.
Conservative Republicans in the Midwest
slowly withdrew their support of
the greenback scheme, associating it
with the Radicals. Many eastern
Republicans had never supported the
idea. While the issue appeared to have
potential for the Republicans, the
Radical viewpoint would ultimately be
squelched in the wake of intraparty
squabbles. Because of their lack of consis-
tency on the issue and Pendleton's
willingness to make greenbacks his calling
card, Pendleton quickly assumed
leadership of the issue. The 1867 election
returns were in part a result of its
growing importance. Instead of deflecting
interest from Reconstruction issues and
strengthening Republican power in
the Midwest, the Ohio Idea coalesced
support around Pendleton. 18
The Pendleton Plan, or the "Ohio
Idea" as it became known, coupled with
the resounding Democratic victory in the
October 1867 election, elevated
Pendleton to leading midwestern
contender for the presidential nomination.19
With the New Year came another state
convention. The Ohio gathering was
so anxious to become the first state to
endorse Pendleton that it set aside the
rules and adopted such a resolution at
the outset of the proceedings. The con-
vention then sent for the awaiting
Pendleton, who addressed them briefly on
the key issues.20 Before
adjourning, delegates adopted a series of resolutions
that reflected Pendleton's ideas. After restating their opposition to
Congressional Reconstruction and the
proposed Fourteenth Amendment, they
concluded with resolutions on financial
questions which echoed the major fea-
Cincinnati Enquirer, May 20, June 3, 6, 26, July 12, 18, 29, Aug. 24, Oct.
17, 18,
Nov. 1, 1867, Jan. 4, 1868.
18. Montgomery, Beyond
Equality, 340-56; Benedict, A Compromise of
Principle, 257-78.
19. Pendleton began an extensive letter
writing campaign encompassing the
country while the Cincinnati Enquirer
boosted him at home in Ohio. Cincinnati
Enquirer, Oct. 22, 25, 28, Nov. 9, 11, 14, Dec. 24, 26, 30, 1867,
Jan. 6, 1868;
New York Times, Oct. 24, 1867; New York Herald, Oct. 21, 1867;
Roseboom,
Civil War Era, 464-65; Samuel S. Cox to Marble, Nov. 11, 1867, Marble
Papers;
Pendleton to M. W. Cluskey, May 24, June
2, 8, 16, 1868, Pendleton
Miscellaneous Manuscripts, Western
Kentucky University Library, Bowling
Green; Pendleton to J. Sterling Morton,
Dec. 3, 1867, Jan. 23, April 9, 1868,
Morton Family Papers, Chicago Historical
Society, Chicago; Pendleton to
Unknown, Dec. 25, 1867, Pendleton
Miscellaneous Manuscripts, Boston Public
Library, Boston; Pendleton to Sylvanus
Cadwallader, Feb. 2, 1868, Sylvanus
Cadwallader Papers, Manuscript Division,
Library of Congress.
20. Cincinnati Enquirer, Jan. 9,
1868; New York Times, Jan. 12, 1868.
136 OHIO HISTORY
tures of the Ohio Idea. The Enquirer,
though supportive of more inflation,
eventually concurred.21
The Pendleton movement swept much of the
Midwest and gained enough
support to influence congressional
activity. In January 1868, Republicans in
both houses launched a counterattack by
voting to end the contraction of
greenbacks.22 For the time being, however,
Congressional Republicans
failed to establish a coherent policy,
giving added impetus to Pendleton's can-
didacy. Democrats in Nebraska, West
Virginia, Indiana, Missouri, Kentucky,
and Minnesota joined with Ohio in
declaring their support for him.23 Fueled
by this groundswell, Pendleton tried to
influence the Democratic National
Committee in its decision regarding the
location and date for the national
convention. He hoped for an early
meeting in a midwestern city. He ob-
tained neither objective. National
Chairman August Belmont, the leader of
the eastern Democratic banking interests
known as "swallow-tails," blocked
these attempts and convinced the
committee to accept the bid of New York
City.24 Belmont's strong-arm
tactics indicated the strength of the hard-money
wing of the party, but the selection did
not dampen Pendleton's spirits.
Members of his organization in New York
had been working hard and re-
mained optimistic. By March, Pendleton
could see his support coalescing.
The Midwest was firm, largely due to its
agrarian composition, and he was
confident of carrying Oregon,
California, Nevada, and hopeful about
Pennsylvania, Connecticut, and Indiana.
By April all the midwestern states
backed his candidacy except Missouri,
but the Enquirer was sure of its support
as well. Based on his experience in
1864, Pendleton believed these states
could create a surge in the early
balloting and stampede hesitant delegates.
But he did not delude himself,
recognizing that the battle would not be easy.25
21. Cincinnati Enquirer, Jan. 9,
10, 1868; American Annual Cyclopaedia and
Register of Important Events of the
Year 1868, vol. 8 (New York, 1869),
601-03;
Destler, American Radicalism, 41-42;
Roseboom, Civil War Era, 466.
22. Barrett, Greenbacks and
Resumption, 167-68; Alexander D. Noyes, Forty
Years of American Finance: A Short
History of the Government and People of the
United States Since the Civil War,
1865-1907 (New York, 1909), 15-16;
James
M. McPherson, Ordeal by Fire: The
Civil War and Reconstruction (New York,
1982), 540-41.
23. Cincinnati Enquirer, Jan. 11,
14, 20, 31, 1868; New York World, Jan. 8-9,
1868.
24. The "swallow-tail"
Democrats were upper-class New Yorkers such as Samuel
Tilden, Samuel Barlow, and August
Belmont who favored a hard money policy and
the National Bank System. Mushkat, Reconstruction
of the New York Democracy,
34-35, 121; Irving Katz, August
Belmont: A Political Biography (New York,
1968), 170-71.
25. Pendleton to J. Sterling Morton,
Jan. 23, March 12, 25, April 9, June 20,
1868, Morton Family Papers; New York
Herald, June 11, 1868; David Black, King
of Fifth Avenue: The Fortunes of
August Belmont (New York, 1981),
303-04;
Destler, American Radicalism, 42.
George Hunt Pendleton 137
In an odd twist, the State Sovereignty
Democrats supported Salmon P.
Chase for the presidency, despite his
long advocacy of universal suffrage, uni-
versal amnesty for southerners, and the
National Bank System. Chase
strongly opposed the Ohio Idea. While
remaining anathema to Pendleton and
his supporters, Chase toned down his
more prickly positions by arguing that
the suffrage issue should be left to state
legislatures. He also expressed his
opposition to the special tax status of
bondholders despite his hard-money
stance. Alexander Long, one-time friend
of Pendleton, apparently now viewed
him as a political rival and opposed the
Ohio Idea. Long was bitter about
Pendleton's rising political fortunes on
an issue Long believed was his own.
As a result, he began a petty and
personal crusade to take back control of the
Ohio Democracy by insidiously suggesting
that Pendleton could help his fu-
ture political prospects by withdrawing
as a candidate and leading the Chase
movement at the convention. Unwilling to
betray his political philosophy or
his supporters and doggedly determined
to maintain control of the Ohio
Democratic machinery, Pendleton refused.26
In this mixture of politics and
personality, Clement L. Vallandigham
joined Long in letting personal concerns
interfere with party considerations.
Vallandigham remained upset over his
1867 defeat for a Senate seat by Allen
G. Thurman, whom Pendleton had eventually
supported. Pendleton may have
believed that Thurman was a better
leader for a party trying to move beyond
the war. Thurman's early acceptance of
the Ohio Idea played a role, too. The
fact that delegates to the Ohio
convention supported Thurman over
Vallandigham undoubtedly influenced
Pendleton as well, because he was seek-
ing the support of those same people for
the presidential nomination. More
importantly, although he had originally
endorsed Vallandigham for the seat at
the 1867 state convention, Pendleton
realized that public support for him now
would create too close an association
with a man many eastern Democrats
considered a political pariah. Such a
mistake would affect his chances for
nomination. Vallandigham remained a
nominal advocate of Pendleton, but
made Chase his second choice. Belmont
joined Vallandigham in favoring
Chase. Belmont saw his opposition to the
Ohio Idea as more important than
26. Frederick J. Blue, Salmon P.
Chase: A Life of Politics (Kent, Ohio, 1987),
286-91; Coleman, Election of 1868, 68-80,
119, 129-40; J. W. Schuckers, The
Life and Public Services of Salmon
Portland Chase, United States Senator and
Governor of Ohio; Secretary of the
Treasury, and Chief-Justice of the United States
(New York, 1874), 578, 589; New York
World, June 9, 1868; Alexander Long to
Salmon P. Chase, April 6, 11, 1868,
Chase to Long, April 8, 19, 1868, J. W.
Schuckers to Long, April 30, June 15,
1868, M. S. Hawley to Long, June 18,
1868, Alexander Long Papers, Cincinnati
Historical Society, Cincinnati. In spite
of his outspoken dissent, the Pendleton
Escort invited Long to join them in their
trek to the convention. He undoubtedly
declined. Invitation, May 22, 1868,
Long Papers.
138 OHIO HISTORY
the need to aid the party in developing
its southern strength. Challenged by
Tammany Hall and the New Albany Regency,
two competing interests within
the New York Democracy, Belmont and the
swallow-tails sought to gain con-
trol of the party in their home state.
Perhaps Chase was just a diversion who
would draw attention away from the
Pendleton Plan and open the door for an-
other candidate more to the liking of
Belmont. Whatever his intent, Belmont
was cautious and did not wish to open
the party up to new potent leaders.27
Pendleton also faced several other
serious contenders for the presidential
nomination. Some Indiana Democrats pushed Thomas Hendricks even
though he had publicly stated he
preferred the Senate. Hendricks was con-
nected to the National Bank System,
having sat on the board of directors of a
branch in his home state. General
Francis P. Blair, Jr., of Missouri, who had
previously been a Republican, was also
supported by some Democrats, but
Chase seemed the more obvious choice
should the convention decide to go
outside the party. Many southerners
favored General Winfield S. Hancock be-
cause of his friendly administration of
Louisiana and Texas following the war.
Governor Horatio Seymour of New York was
the strongest possibility for the
hard-money men. Seymour opposed the Ohio
Idea, but was conservative on
Reconstruction issues and had a war
record that attracted former Peace
Democrats. As in 1864, he repeatedly
declined to have his name used, but
left the door open just enough to keep
his supporters interested. Pendleton
respected Seymour as a politician and as
an administrator, but did not agree
with his financial policies. In Seymour,
eastern Democrats found a logical
compromise candidate, though no single
strong alternative surfaced against
Pendleton. The Buckeye's prospects
looked good.28
Newspapers were rife with rumors about
various machinations before the
convention. Amidst all of the hearsay,
it was obvious that the party remained
deeply divided. Ultra-inflationists and
Belmont's swallow-tails comprised the
extremes, with Pendleton in the middle.
While those who favored extreme in-
flation probably could ultimately support
Pendleton, the eastern hard-money
advocates, with money and influence to
employ against him, could not.
Though Pendleton entered the convention
with 149 convention votes in his
27. Moore, "Ohio in National
Politics," 258-60; James L. Vallandigham, A Life
of Clement L. Vallandigham (Baltimore, 1872), 422-24; Cincinnati Enquirer, May
13, 1923; Cincinnati Commercial, Feb.
7, 1868; New York World, Feb. 5, 1868;
Katz, August Belmont, 167-71;
Mushkat, Reconstruction of the New York
Democracy, 113-42; Horace Samuel Merrill, Bourbon Leader:
Grover Cleveland
and the Democratic Party, The Library of American Biography, ed. Oscar Handlin
(Boston, 1957), 24-46; Montgomery, Beyond
Equality, 351.
28. Coleman, Election of 1868, 21-35,
149-86; Montgomery, Beyond Equality,
346; Blue, Salmon P. Chase, 292;
Stewart Mitchell, Horatio Seymour of New York
(New York, 1970), 383-411; DeAlva S.
Alexander, A Political History of the State
of New York, vol. 3 (1909; reprint, Port Washington, N.Y., 1969),
89-97; New
York Times, July 10, 1868.
George Hunt Pendleton 139
pocket, more than any other candidate,
his organization suffered from an ab-
sence of efficient leadership because of
the struggle between Pendleton,
Vallandigham, and Long. As one Chase
booster noted, these personality dif-
ferences enhanced the Chief Justice's
prospects since the divisions prevented
Pendleton from trading and bartering
with other delegates. In spite of decided
opposition, his supporters, in the form
of the "Pendleton Escort," were ready
to take New York by storm.29
In the sweltering heat of July,
Democrats from all across the nation de-
scended on New York City. In spite of
Belmont's influence and Seymour's
early convention speech blasting paper
currency, soft money men controlled
the platform committee. On older issues,
the party acknowledged that slavery
and secession were casualties of the
war, pleaded for the immediate restoration
of the southern states, and asked for
amnesty for the former Confederates.
The platform also railed against the
Congressional Republican plans for
Reconstruction while reiterating the
partisan position on states' rights and
African-American suffrage. Turning to
the new and important issues of na-
tional finance, the members of the
committee espoused four separate resolu-
tions. First, they called for the rapid
payment of the national debt with the
"lawful money of the United
States," unless specifically designated in coin.
Second, they demanded equal taxation of
all types of property including gov-
ernment bonds. In the third resolution,
the delegates advocated one currency
for all Americans, further solidifying
the party's stance in support of paying
the five-twenty bonds in greenbacks.
Finally, they insisted that the govern-
ment stop the high expenditures
presently being committed to support the
armed forces still active in southern
states and through appropriations for the
administration of the Freedmen's
Bureau. Economy in government,
Democrats believed, was the quickest
route to debt payment and lower taxes.
The platform did not directly call for
the destruction of the National Bank
System, nor did it include a provision
to return the country to specie pay-
ments within fifteen years. The planks
could be associated, however, with no
candidate more than Pendleton.30
29. Marble to Pendleton, Nov. 23, 1867,
Pendleton to Marble, Dec. 5, 1867,
March 3, 1868, Marble Papers; Samuel
Ward to Salmon P. Chase, June 26, 1868,
Salmon P. Chase Papers, Manuscript
Division, Library of Congress, Washington,
DC; Boston Daily Courier, June
11, 22, 1868; New York Evening Post, Feb. 13,
1868; New York Leader, March 28,
April 11, 18, 1868; New York Herald, Jan. 10,
27, April 25, 1868; New York World, Feb.
1, May 9, June 1, 9, 26, July 2-4, 22,
1868; Cincinnati Gazette, Feb.
27, July 1-3, 6, 1868; Cincinnati Enquirer, May 2,
21, 29, June 1, 10, 1868; Cincinnati
Commercial, Feb. 8, July 2-4, 1868.
30. The National Labor Union endorsed
these principles. Official Proceedings
of the National Democratic
Convention, held at New York, July 4-9, 1868
(Boston, 1868), 22-30, 58-59; New
York World, July 8, 1868; Coleman, Election
of 1868, 200-02; Katz, August Belmont, 172-73; Black, King
of Fifth Avenue,
303-05.
140 OHIO HISTORY
The platform was a clear victory for
Pendleton and illustrated the strength
of his support base.31 As a
midwesterner, Pendleton represented many farm-
ers who saw in the Ohio Idea a means to
easier debt repayment through main-
tenance of an expanded currency. Yet
Pendleton undoubtedly hoped to appeal
to another growing group of
voters-labor. The platform echoed Pendleton's
often repeated sentiments for "one
currency for the government and the peo-
ple, the laborer and the office-holder,
the pensioner and the soldier, the pro-
ducer and the bond-holder."32 Edward
Kellogg, a merchant turned author and
financial expert after the Panic of 1837
ruined his business, had begun the
process of influencing trade unionists
to support greenbacks as early as
1848.33 Moreover, Pendleton
realized the practical necessity of recognizing
the growing laboring element in his
hometown of Cincinnati, and perhaps
more importantly in New York City where
much of his strongest political
opposition resided. Representing an
early response by labor, the fledging
National Labor Union supported many of
the principles on currency delineated
in the Democratic platform of 1868.
Though Tammany Hall needed to main-
tain the support of tens of thousands of
immigrant workers, the political ma-
chine was still too powerful to be
forced to capitulate to labor demands. The
other powerful factions within the
eastern Democracy had economic interests
that ran contrary to those of labor and
farmers. In the end, the Ohio Idea was
ahead of its time politically and
economically. Labor was not yet organized
enough to exert the pressure necessary
to overcome the competing political
elements in New York that controlled so
much of the Democracy. Bringing
laborers and farmers together in
political concert awaited another day, and an-
other platform.34
31. Official Proceedings, 59-61;
Coleman, Election of 1868, 201-05; Mitchell,
Horatio Seymour, 417-20; Roseboom, Civil War Era, 466-67; Cincinnati
Commercial, July 6, 1868; Cleveland Plain Dealer, July 7,
1868.
32. Official Proceedings, 58.
33. In the years prior to 1837, land
speculation expanded due to a flurry of rail-
road and canal building. Banks fueled
this growth with expanded credit. President
Andrew Jackson, fearing runaway
speculation, issued the Specie Circular in 1836
requiring all public lands to be
purchased in gold. Jackson's action, combined
with tightened credit in Europe and poor
harvests among American farmers, created
a significant depression in the late
1830s and early 1840s. Kellogg's writings
encouraged some Americans to view paper
currency as the means of preventing
such economic problems. See also Reginald C. McGrane, The Panic
of 1837:
Some Financial Problems of the
Jacksonian Era (Chicago, 1965).
34. Barrett,Greenbacks and
Resumption, 161-73; Destler, American
Radicalism, 44-49; Unger, The Greenback Era, 81-91; New
York World,
September 22, 25, 30-31, 1868; T. V.
Powderly, Thirty Years of Labor, 1859-
1889, In Which the History of the
Attempts to Form Organizations of
Workingmen for the Discussion of
Political, Social, and Economic Questions is
Traced, The National Labor Union of
1866, The Industrial Brotherhood of 1874,
and the Order of the Knights of Labor
of America and the World, The Chief and
George Hunt Pendleton 141
Yet Pendleton's appeal to labor went
well beyond the confines of his own
party. Indeed, Radical Republican
leaders such as Thaddeus Stevens had
sought to tap into a traditional support
base, the trade unionists, by propos-
ing the end of the National Bank System
and the redeeming of five-twenties
in greenbacks. Conservatives within the
Republican Party, however, were no
longer willing to subject themselves to
Stevens' Radical leadership. The
National Bank System represented the
successful war effort against the seces-
sionist South. To disband it would be to
turn their backs on their greatest
achievement. Moreover, many Republicans
viewed the bank as a necessary
component in postwar economic
development. As a result, Stevens' ideas
were rejected and the Republicans stood
for the National Bank System and
hard currency. For labor, this party
position was the last straw. Not only
had they been forgotten in the
Republican scramble for African-American po-
litical equality, but also, in the
waning years of Reconstruction as the politi-
cal system began to focus on other
issues, the Republicans dismissed out of
hand labor currency concerns.
Disillusioned, trade-unionists sought to foster
an independent party movement (Labor
Reform Party) as an offshoot of the
National Labor Union.35
The question facing the convention now
was whether the party would learn
from the mistakes of 1860 and 1864, or
split its platform and nominee again.
Illinois and Iowa, when called upon for
their choice, deferred to the Ohio dele-
gation to name its favorite son. Maine,
however, was too anxious and could
not wait. Stealing Ohio's thunder,
Marcellus Emory of Maine moved, amidst
great clamor, "in behalf of the
laboring masses of Maine" to nominate
Pendleton for President.36 General
George W. McCook of Ohio was left to
second the motion. The nominations of
President Andrew Johnson, Asa
Packer of Pennsylvania, General Hancock,
and Hendricks quickly followed.
The first ballot gave Pendleton a total
of 105 votes to 65 for Johnson, his
nearest competitor, but far short of the
magic two-thirds. Over the next series
of ballots, Pendleton expanded his vote
total to a high of 156 and one-half,
but his hopes plunged when Indiana,
which had supported him to that point,
split between him and Hendricks. As
weary delegates caucused, Pendleton
knew his time had passed. Prepared for
this contingency, he had written a let-
ter of withdrawal to McLean in the
spirit of party unity for use if McLean felt
Pendleton's candidacy was doomed. McLean
thought the moment had arrived
Most Important Principles in the
Preamble of the Knights of Labor Discussed and
Explained with Views of the Author on
Land, Labor and Transportation
(Columbus, Ohio, 1889), 48-89; Foster
Rhea Dulles, Labor in America: A
History, 3rd ed. (New York, 1966), 109-11; Joseph G. Rayback, A
History of
American Labor, 2nd ed. (New York, 1966), 103-28.
35. Montgomery, Beyond Equality, vii-xi,
335-60; New York World, Sept. 22,
25, 30-31, 1868.
36. Official Proceedings, 68.
142 OHIO HISTORY
after the fourth ballot, but the Ohio
delegation wished to press ahead. On the
fifth day, Pendleton's total dropped by
100, and Vallandigham presented the
letter. The Daytonite then worked
unsuccessfully to get the New York delega-
tion to change its vote to Chase. On the
twenty-second ballot, McCook, rep-
resenting Ohio, nominated Horatio
Seymour. He said that Pendleton sup-
ported the idea and that Seymour was a
man who could unite the divided
party. Seymour won the nomination
unanimously.37
Lessons Not Learned
Pendleton's efforts were impaired from
the outset by two major factors.
With Grant's selection by the
Republicans, Pendleton's association with the
Peace Democrats stirred harmful wartime
memories. Nevertheless, Seymour
shared a similar liability. Of greater
significance was the Pendleton Plan.
The two largest eastern states worked
hard to prevent his nomination. When
Indiana's support wavered, angry Ohio
Pendletonians vowed to prevent
Hendricks from winning because some
blamed Pendleton's demise on
Indiana's defection. At the same time,
most Ohioans, except Vallandigham,
refused to support Chase. He was too
identified with the Republicans during
the war and did not represent the views
of midwestern Democrats on most
important political issues. With
Pendleton's support, Ohio led the charge for
Seymour. An eastern nomination for the
second consecutive convention
might open the door for a midwestern
candidate in 1872. Though Seymour
did not accept the Ohio Idea, he was
more sound than Chase on the other as-
pects of the platform that concerned
Ohioans.
The party had learned very little from
the 1864 campaign. Though the
midwestern Democracy, with support from
the South, had gained strength, it
could not totally direct the convention.
Too many southern delegates had fa-
vored candidates to whom they had closer
ties such as Johnson and Hancock,
and did not recognize the benefits of
the Pendleton Plan for the South.
Because of regional divisions, economic
diversity, and intrastate power strug-
gles, the party once again failed to
produce harmony. In short, the party did
not understand how to proceed as a
minority. Pendleton had hoped that by
winning southern support, he could pull
eastern Democrats along kicking and
screaming, and he almost succeeded. The
end result, however, was a ticket and
platform representative of a divided and
floundering party.38
37. Ibid., 66-174; Coleman, Election
of 1868, 208-12; Mitchell, Horatio
Seymour, 422-32; Blue, Salmon P. Chase, 294-95; Cincinnati
Enquirer, July 10,
14, 1868; New York Times, July
10, 1868; New York World, July 10, 1868;
Cincinnati Commercial, July 9, 10, 1868; Cleveland Plain Dealer, July
9-11,
1868; Diary and Correspondence of
Salmon P. Chase (New York, 1971), 520-21.
38. Cincinnati Gazette, July 10,
1868; Cincinnati Commercial, July 10-11,
George Hunt Pendleton 143
Democratic losses in October elections
in Maine, Ohio and Pennsylvania
foreshadowed defeat in November when
Grant routed Seymour. The result was
particularly bitter to Pendleton when
Seymour lost in Ohio by a margin of
41,090 votes. Intraparty recriminations
filled the air immediately. The
Enquirer tried to soften the drubbing by unearthing the standard
Democratic
explanation that Republicans stole the
election through fraud. As the editor
of the New York World and
spokesman for eastern Democrats, Manton
Marble disagreed. While he acknowledged
that Congressional Reconstruction
programs harmed Seymour in the South,
the greater fault rested with the Ohio
Idea. In retrospect, each interpretation
contained an element of truth. Federal
troops stationed in several
unreconstructed states had indeed interfered with the
voting process. Eastern hard-money
Democrats either had shunned Seymour
because of the party platform or had not
voted in silent protest. Moreover,
the contrast between Seymour's
vacillating wartime record and Grant's hero-
ism posed an almost insurmountable
barrier to any possible Democratic vic-
tory. Even so, neither McLean nor Marble
gave the Ohio Idea its just due.
To have ignored the financial issues
would have cost Democrats valuable
support in the Midwest. But Pendleton's
innovative program had even larger
dimensions. When the Republicans
concentrated on Reconstruction issues
and waved the "bloody shirt,"
the Democrats were placed on the defensive.39
In that sense, the Ohio Idea implicitly
accepted the results of the Civil War,
neutralized any lingering issues
connected to Reconstruction, created the
means for Democrats to forge sectional
reconciliation, and provided them with
the possibility of formulating fresh
programs more in tune with the future
than the past. Yet Pendleton buttressed
all of this progress on a new interpre-
tation of the well-worn Jacksonian
principle. Pendleton willingly took on
new issues, but preserved the old party
ideology in an effort to unite party fac-
tions. Yet not all Democrats were
willing to go along. Whatever the reasons
for failure in 1868, Pendleton
understood that both he and his party stood on
the threshold of a new political
focus.40
The debate over the Ohio Idea and the
campaign of 1868 are significant for
more than just what they portray about
Pendleton and the Democratic Party.
Indeed, they suggest much about the
political arena following the end of the
1868; Cincinnati Enquirer, May
13, 1923; Coleman, Election of 1868, 212-14;
Charles R. Williams, ed., Diary and
Letters of Rutherford B. Hayes: Nineteenth
President of the United States (Columbus, Ohio, 1926), 3:53-54; Blue, Salmon P.
Chase, 294-95.
39. The Republican practice of equating
their party with the Union cause and pa-
triotism and the Democrats with the
South's cause and rebellion was known as
"waving the bloody shirt."
40. Letter cited in Coleman, Election
of 1868, 336-39, 362-79; Cincinnati
Enquirer, Nov. 22, 1868; Cincinnati Gazette, Nov. 4, 1868;
Cincinnati
Commercial. Nov. 4, 1868.
144 OHIO HISTORY
Civil War. The Democratic factionalism
which adversely affected the cam-
paign was quite similar to the divisions
in the party in antebellum America.
Differences frequently divided the party
in the first half of the nineteenth cen-
tury, leading to the rise of various
regional political favorites and ultimately
the 1860 schism that precipitated the
Civil War. The Republicans remained
largely a northern party while
"waving the bloody shirt" and reminding voters
that it was the party of Abraham Lincoln
and of the Union. Little had
changed in terms of the conflict between
and within parties as a result of the
war. In fact, most of the antebellum
leaders continued to debate similar is-
sues following the conflict. Certainly,
as evidenced by the contention over
debt financing, there were new issues,
but they were still contested on the ba-
sis of old ideology, even if a man such
as Pendleton sought to interpret it dif-
ferently. Consequently, the Democrats
continued to experience debilitating
factionalism. Pendleton had attempted to
cast an innovative spin on his par-
ty's ideology and failed. Yet he was not
one to give up, and in the remainder
of his political career, he continued to
seek for that elusive issue upon which
to rebuild the strength of his party. He
would eventually find what he
thought was it in civil service reform.
THOMAS S. MACH
George Hunt Pendleton, The Ohio Idea
and Political Continuity in Reconstruction
America
The severe defeat of the Democrats in
the 1866 election in Ohio and across
the country left some of the party's
political positions meaningless. With a
Republican majority in Congress and
Reconstruction issues under its control,
the Democratic Party pinned its future
on the ideas of a politician in the
throes of resurrecting a political
career. George Hunt Pendleton, a leading
Democrat from Ohio, had made a name for
himself during the Civil War as a
Peace Democrat representing southwestern
Ohio in Congress. He had run
with General George McClellan in 1864
for the vice-presidency, but with the
war won and the Republicans waving the
bloody shirt, Pendleton seemed des-
tined for obscurity. Following the war,
the Democrats were adrift in terms of
policies, issues and leaders. They had
supported President Johnson, but his
growing unpopularity and unwillingness
to cooperate with them promised
years of campaign defeats. The Democrats
continued to show a lack of imag-
ination in 1866 when they campaigned in
opposition to Congressional
Reconstruction. 1
Pendleton initially was no different
from other Democrats; he followed the
same obstructionist policies and lost
his 1866 bid for Congress. But
Pendleton realized this approach,
however much sense it made in the short
run, was an expedient that failed to
rebuild the southern Democracy, did not
restore the prewar party's sectional
alignments, and lent credence to
Republican attacks that the Democrats
had flirted with treason during the war.
Thomas S. Mach is an Associate Professor
of History at Mount Vernon Nazarene
College in Mount Vernon, Ohio. The
author would like to thank Professor Jerome
Mushkat for his steadfast encouragement
and helpful comments in the completion
of this article.
1. Eric L. McKitrick, Andrew Johnson
and Reconstruction (Chicago, 1960),
274-325; Robert D. Sawrey, Dubious
Victor: The Reconstruction Debate in Ohio
(Lexington, Ky., 1992), 59-67; W. R.
Brock, An American Crisis: Congress and
Reconstruction, 1865-1867 (London, 1963), 105-22; Floyd O. Rittenhouse,
"George Hunt Pendleton: With
Special Reference to His Congressional Career"
(Master's thesis, The Ohio State University,
1932), 53-55; Clifford H. Moore,
"Ohio in National Politics,
1865-1896," Ohio Archaeological and Historical
Society Publications, 37 (April, 1928), 236-40.