Ohio History Journal




JAMES F

JAMES F. RICHARDSON

 

Urban Political Change

in the Progressive Era

 

The nature and sources of political change in the early twentieth

century are among the favorite topics for assessment and reassessment

among American historians. The degree of concern is understandable,

for the Progressive period witnessed considerable expansion in govern-

mental functions and major changes in governmental structure. This

transformation in form and function was perhaps more pronounced in

the nation's cities than in any other segment of the society, and urban

historicans have joined enthusiastically in the debate over the char-

acter and definition of progressivism.

In the 1940s Arthur M. Schlesinger, Jr., set the terms for much of

this debate by arguing that the history of American liberalism, of

which progressivism represented one chapter, consisted of efforts by

 

 

Books reviewed in this essay:

The Age of Urban Reform: New Perspectives on the Progressive Era.

Edited by Michael H. Ebner and Eugene M. Tobin. (Port Washing-

ton, NY: Kennikat Press, 1977, viii + 213p.; tables, maps, biblio-

graphic guide, notes, index. $12.95 cloth; $7.95 paper.)

Progressive Cities: The Commission Government Movement in Amer-

ica, 1901-1920. By Bradley Robert Rice. (Austin: The University of

Texas Press, 1977. xix + 160p.; tables, appendix, notes, selected

bibliography, index. $10.95.)

Better City Government: Innovation in American Urban Politics, 1850-

1937. By Kenneth Fox. (Philadelphia: Temple University Press,

1977. xxi + 222p.; notes, bibliographic essay, index. $15.00.)

The Politics of Efficiency: Municipal Administration and Reform in

America, 1880-1920. By Martin J. Schiesl. (Berkeley: University of

California Press, 1977. ix + 259p.; notes, bibliography, index. $11.75.)

 

 

 

 

James F. Richardson is Professor of History and Urban Studies at The University of

Akron.



Urban Political Change 311

Urban Political Change                                             311

 

other segments of the politically active society to limit the power of

the business community, usually through an increase in the level of

state regulation and control.1 Writing within this framework, histor-

ians like Russel Blaine Nye and Hoyt Landon Warner emphasized

the successful struggles of reform mayors such as Tom Johnson of

Cleveland, Samuel "Golden Rule" Jones of Toledo and Hazen Pin-

gree of Detroit against the alliance of utilities, traction companies

and corrupt political bosses that dominated late nineteenth-century

urban politics.2

However, this sanguine liberalism faded rapidly. Reflecting the

more skeptical attitude toward reform movements prevalent at the

height of the Cold War in the 1950s, George Mowry and especially

Richard Hofstadter painted a portrait of the progressives as more

self-serving. These historians posited a late-nineteenth-century "status

revolution" which saw urban Protestants-ministers, some lawyers,

small businessmen-decline in social prestige and political power.

Threatened by the emergence of a plutocracy above and a polygot,

largely immigrant proletariat below, these men and women entered

politics to defend, and if possible advance, their social standing in the

community. In their opposition to graft, corruption and boss rule,

they claimed to speak for the larger community; in fact, said Hof-

stadter, they often equated their own parochial middle-class interest

with the public interest itself. For example, by ending patronage appoint-

ments to the public service they could limit lower-class access to city

jobs and enhance the career opportunities of the well educated.3

In the 1960s the "status revolution" thesis of Hofstadter and the

lingering liberalism of Schlesinger came under fire from a new gener-

ation of historians. Gabriel Kolko and James Weinstein virtually

denied that there was any such thing as a progressive movement.4

Writing from within the context of an emerging New Left milieu,

Kolko argued that on the national level, legislation regulating business

was the work of the business community itself in its struggle to ra-

tionalize its operations, eliminate unwanted competition and create

orderly and predictable markets. Weinstein and Samuel Hays found

the same processes at work on the urban scene where successful busi-

ness and professional men provided the chief impetus for the wide-

 

1. Arthur M. Schlesinger, Jr., The Age of Jackson (Boston, 1945).

2. Russel Blaine Nye, Midwestern Progressive Politics (East Lansing, 1951); Hoyt

Landon Warner, Progressivism in Ohio (Columbus, 1964).

3. George Mowry, The Era of Theodore Roosevelt, 1900-1912 (New York, 1958);

Richard Hofstadter, The Age of Reform (New York, 1955).

4. Gabriel Kolko, The Triumph of Conservatism (New York, 1964); James Wein-

stein, The Corporate Ideal in the Liberal State (Boston, 1968).



312 OHIO HISTORY

312                                                    OHIO HISTORY

 

spread adoption of the commission and city manager forms of mu-

nicipal governance. Using Pittsburgh as his case study, Hays held

that it was successful businessmen with metropolitan or even nation-

wide interests and the best educated professionals who led the way in

changing the city's charter and the organization of its school system.

These structural innovations had the effect of reducing local and lower-

class influence in the new centralized systems dominated by an upper-

middle-class administrative elite.5

Hays' interpretation meshed well with that offered by Robert Weibe

in his Search for Order, 1877-1920, a major statement of the thesis

that American life underwent a fundamental transformation in the

Progressive era as people revamped their institutions to make them

compatible with an economy increasingly dominated by large orga-

nizations. Wiebe and Hays thus placed the political changes of the

first two decades of the twentieth century in the context of a modern-

izing society marked by an increasing scale of organization and cen-

tralization of decision making.6

Perhaps reflecting the more relaxed political atmosphere of the

1970s, the books under review offer a more positive and less conspira-

torial portrait of urban progressivism. Even where the authors stress

the major role played by businessmen, they also emphasize the often

beneficial results of the changes introduced. Kenneth Fox takes the

most revisionist view. He does not think that businessmen as leaders

or the business corporation as a model had much influence on urban

political change. In his Better City Government: Innovation in Ameri-

can Urban Politics, 1850-1937, Fox attempts to conceptualize broad

areas of American political history. His technique is to delineate one

ideological perspective per period as if all politically active people

shared a common system of values and approaches. For example, he

argues that the years from about 1850 to 1890 were characterized by

"pragmatic innovation." He includes under this heading both the

urban political machines and state interference in municipal affairs.

He recognizes that the local organizations and state intervention had

different and often strongly antagonistic constituencies, yet his desire

to find a single phrase for a forty-year period leads him to lump them

together. What one misses in Fox's treatment is a sense of the debate

between adherents of different governmental philosophies as to how

cities should respond to the problems generated internally and to

national economic and social change.

 

5. Samuel Hays, "The Politics of Municipal Reform in the Progressive Era," Paci-

fic Northwest Quarterly, LV (October 1964), 157-69; "The Shame of the Cities Revis-

ited: The Case of Pittsburgh," unpublished paper.

6. Robert H. Wiebe, The Search for Order, 1877-1920 (New York, 1967).



Urban Political Change 313

Urban Political Change                                       313

 

The heart of the book lies in Fox's treatment of the origins and

development, but not the implementation, of the next phase of mu-

nicipal political philosophy, which he calls "functional innovation"

and sees as dominant from the 1890s to the late 1920s. According to

Fox, the intellectual bases of "functional innovation" rested on three

groups: jurists who developed the theory of the municipal corporation,

especially John Dillon; scholars specializing in public administration

who urged that states grant cities sufficient legal power for them to

deal effectively with their own problems; and a new generation of na-

tional reformers for whom improved city government took the place of

the previous generation's concern for national civil service reform.

Thus Fox concludes that "functional innovation" replaced prag-

matic innovation by the 1890s, as the law, political science, and good

government advocates nationally came to focus on the cities' govern-

mental problems. The movement received organizational focus with the

establishment in 1894 of the National Municipal League supported

by social scientists out to build a rationale for municipal public

administration as a problem-solving activity and by reformers with

national interests and aspirations. Fox is more interested in these na-

tional networks than he is in the distribution of power and the nature

of political activity within cities. Unfortunately, he does not link his

national groups with specific changes within cities to enable the reader

to see the relationships between ideas and advocacy and action. De-

spite his use of the term "functional innovation," Fox does not say

anything about the people who performed the functions, the bureau-

crats and professional administrators who came to play such key roles

in urban government.

In his most original chapters, Fox deals with the work of the pro-

fessionals of the Bureau of the Census in promoting the expansion

of city governmental activities. The Bureau advocated uniform mu-

nicipal accounting systems and gave per capita estimates of cities'

spending patterns in its Statistics of Cities. In the first decade of the

twentieth century, major cities did not spend as much per capita as

they had in 1880. Health services were especially impoverished.

Between 1912 and 1930, however, cities spent considerably more for

health and education; also cities became more alike in their allocation

of resources, thus reducing the previously wide variations in what dif-

ferent cities would spend on particular services. In Fox's view, func-

tional innovation reached its peak by the late 1920s. Thus he would

deny that World War I formed the dividing line between a period of

reform and a period of reaction. If anything, cities devoted more

money to public welfare activities in the 1920s than they had pre-

viously. Supporters of the notion of an urban progressive movement



314 OHIO HISTORY

314                                                OHIO HISTORY

 

before the war, such as Martin Schiesl, could counter that it was in

these years that cities first modernized their governmental machinery

and expanded their activities. In this view the key innovation was the

acceptance of a particular task as a public responsibility. Cities in the

1920s merely provided more money for previously established depart-

ments and bureaus.

Chronologically, the fullest development of functional innovation

coincided with national trends leading to a weakening position of

central cities as the outward movement of people and business out-

stripped the cities' ability to annex these newly settled areas. In the

late 1920s some observers proposed the creation of metropolitan gov-

ernments as the answer to the service needs of metropolitan areas.

Fox asserts that political scientist Paul Studenski destroyed the case

for metro government at that time, but he does not demonstrate how,

except to say that Studenski proved that urban governments were not

going to collapse in the absence of metropolitan consolidation. Per-

haps Studenski and later Roderick McKenzie did show that central

cities and independent suburbs could both survive, but many schol-

ars believed throughout the 1950s and into the 1960s that metropoli-

tan government would help balance needs and resources and provide

better services. Even where the voters rejected metropolitan govern-

ment, as they did in Cleveland in 1959, appointed authorities were

subsequently created to administer particular services on a metropoli-

tan-area-wide basis, thus bypassing the established city and suburban

governmental entities. If I understand what Fox means by functional

innovation, such bodies as the Regional Transit Authority, the Cleve-

land-Cuyahoga County Port Authority, and the Cleveland Regional

Sewer District could be considered as examples.

Fox believes that the great depression of the 1930s introduced a

new cycle of urban political development and thought, whose intellec-

tual base can be found in Our Cities, the 1937 report of the National

Urbanism Committee. Our Cities emphasized the inability of cities to

cope with the demands generated by national economic trends and

argued that henceforth the federal government would have to play

a much more active role in urban affairs. For the next few decades

urban theorists combined Keynesian economics and pluralist poli-

tics in their analyses of and prescriptions for urban government. He

cites the work of such scholars as Robert Dahl, Wallace Sayre and

Herbert Kaufman, and Robert Wood in support of this position.

This section seems tacked on, as if Fox felt constrained to offer an

overarching conceptualization for the decades after his title terminal

date of 1937. There is no question that some scholars did offer the kind

of analyses and prescriptions he describes, but the same could be



Urban Political Change 315

Urban Political Change                                     315

 

said for earlier advocates of functional innovation. They coincided

chronologically with the supporters of the commission and city man-

ager forms and a vigorous municipal socialist movement. Fox men-

tions these movements only in connection with the functionalists'

attitude toward them and so overlooks an opportunity to place advo-

cates of functional innovation in the context of the ideological debate

of their time.

Perhaps it is unfair to criticize an author for not writing the book

the reviewer wishes he had written rather than the one he did write;

still, Fox would have made a more useful contribution if he had con-

centrated on the relationships between the activities of the Bureau

of the Census and the processes of innovation in particular cities.

Then his readers would have a better sense of the interaction between

the advocates of change on the national level and local decision mak-

ers.

In the most impressive of the books under review, The Politics of

Efficiency, Martin J. Schiesl does provide a convincing study of the

impact of political theory upon innovations in government. He has

examined both the advocates of municipal efficiency and the imple-

mentation of their ideas in a number of cities. Schiesl's concept of

municipal efficiency is a more accurate description of what people

were saying and doing during these years than is Fox's term func-

tional innovation. The advocates of efficiency saw government by

party organizations as the great evil because the latter were more in-

terested in organizational survival and aggrandizement than they

were in providing good services at low cost. Party government re-

quired patronage for party workers and the extraction of campaign

funds and other organizational expenses from civil servants, legiti-

mate businessmen and vice entrepreneurs who needed governmental

support or protection. Party government could not be efficient govern-

ment because its priorities put a low premium on administrative com-

petence.

Efficient government most often meant the promotion of economic

growth, otherwise known as the public interest. Its promoters took it

as axiomatic that there was a definable public interest which tran-

scended any private interests and that the purpose of government was

to promote this public interest in the most effective manner possible.

Hence their model of government was the business corporation where

there was an agreement upon goals, and the task at hand was to de-

fine the most effective means of attaining those goals.

Specifically, efficiency could be achieved if the executive could be

strengthened, party labels eliminated in municipal elections, effective

procedures of budgeting and accounting introduced, men with execu-



316 OHIO HISTORY

316                                                 OHIO HISTORY

 

tive ability and experience appointed to administrative posts, and pub-

lic servants insulated from patronage removals and partisan pres-

sures generally. The city manager movement with its separation of

administration from policy making, its nonpartisan at-large elec-

tions for Council, its appointed administrator, and its explicit model-

ing of municipal government upon the business corporation embodied

all of the major themes advanced in the name of efficiency.

Schiesl asserts that there was no necessary conflict between effi-

ciency and social welfare. Reformers believed that more efficient gov-

ernment meant better services and more humane government. Thus

Schiesl disagrees with Augustus Cerillo and other scholars who have

found the Mitchel administration in New York City long on econ-

omy and efficiency and short on social welfare. According to Schiesl,

Mitchel and his followers saw a necessary connection between effi-

ciency and social welfare. If the books were not kept properly, the

chances are that the clients would be neglected. In addition, with care-

ful budgeting and accounting controls, less money would be wasted

and more made available for social welfare expenditures. Government

could thus expand its activities without unduly burdening the tax-

payers.

Schiesl also gives high marks to an earlier New York reform mayor,

Seth Low, who served, as did Mitchel, just one term after his election

in 1901. Melvin Holli, the historian who originally developed the dis-

tinction between structural reform and social reform, had treated the

Low Administration as the epitome of structural reform, that is a

single-minded concern for economy and efficiency in government with-

out any interest in social reform or social welfare.7 Schiesl has ob-

viously learned from Holli but denies the validity of his sharp dichot-

omy between structural and social reform and uses Low as an

example of an urban reformer who combined both perspectives.

The book's final chapters deal with the increasing bureaucratiza-

tion of municipal government and the development of the commis-

sion and city manager forms. Such changes emphasized administra-

tive independence and competence and deemphasized popular

control and the role of elected officials. To make these changes

compatible with a formally democratic tradition, the reformers needed

to redefine democracy so that it "became less a system of stimulating

greater individual participation in the decision-making process and

more a method of making decisions which insured efficiency in civic

administration while requiring some measure of responsiveness to

 

 

7. Melvin G. Holli, Reform in Detroit: Hazen S. Pingree and Urban Politics (New

York, 1969).



Urban Political Change 317

Urban Political Change                                        317

 

public opinion" (p.149). Under this model civil servants would need

to be competent and selflessly devoted to the public interest rather

than to individual concerns. Professionals such as engineers and pub-

lic health specialists looked to their peers around the country, even

internationally, for approval and support, not to local elected officials.

Within the city they built alliances with constituencies organized on a

functional rather than a neighborhood basis. Perforce, these profes-

sionals and administrators became highly active politically as they

sought larger budgets and more autonomy for their operations. Their

values were those of the expert and scientist, values often not shared

by the majority of the city's population. As their power grew, that of

the ward-based politicians and their constituencies declined.

The city manager form represented the ultimate in structural re-

form and it spread widely in the 1920s. Yet, as Schiesl notes, even

with the benefits provided in more effective government, including

better social services, the structural reformers often failed in building

a permanent political base. A case in point is Cleveland which

adopted the city manager form in the 1920s only to abandon it for

the traditional mayor-council form in the early 1930s.

In an excellent epilogue, entitled "The Model and Political Real-

ity," Schiesl evaluates the lasting strengths and weaknesses of the

politics of efficiency. In overcoming the power of the ward-based ma-

chines, the reformers weakened popular control by stressing the role

of experts and promoting the interests of elites. However, the de-

struction of the machine also facilitated access to important power

centers on the part of functionally organized groups within the city.

No longer would these people have to go through the boss, no longer

would the political organization come between the public and the

public's servants. And even short-lived reform movements often initi-

ated programs and practices that subsequent machine administra-

tions had to maintain. Perhaps the greatest weakness of the pro-

moters of efficiency lay in their failure to anticipate that an insulated

bureaucracy could be every bit as self-serving, if not necessarily cor-

rupt, and unresponsive as the most entrenched political machine.

Schiesl's portrait is a complex one, marked by shadings and nu-

ances, and therefore more accurate than some of the one-dimensional

interpretations of urban progressivism offered by Weinstein and

Hays. He writes well and provides a good balance between analysis

and supporting descriptive detail. Of course he makes a few mis-

takes. One howler is his comment that cities in the progressive period

did not experience the fiscal bind facing contemporary municipali-

ties. He cites Cincinnati and Cleveland frequently, without noting or

apparently knowing that these cities suffered severe financial prob-



318 OHIO HISTORY

318                                                  OHIO HISTORY

 

lems because of state-imposed taxing and borrowing limits. True, the

fiscal crisis then did not arise from the same sources as current finan-

cial problems, but it was a fiscal crisis nonetheless. But, I would not

like to leave Schiesl's book on a negative note. It is the most useful

study we have of urban political change in the late nineteenth and

early twentieth centuries, and it is an especially impressive achieve-

ment for a young scholar's first book.

Bradley Rice has chosen a more limited topic than either Fox or

Schiesl in his Progressive Cities: The Commission Government

Movement in America, 1901-1920; in so doing he has produced a book

that successfully accomplishes its modest aims. He provides a straight-

forward treatment of the adoption of commission government from

its inception in Galveston, Texas, in 1901, until the commission move-

ment gave way to the city manager plan in the late teens. In the com-

mission format, a limited number of commissioners, usually five, com-

bined legislative and executive functions. Each commissioner pre-

sided over a specific administrative area; as a body the commission

served as the city's legislature. Businessmen and others with city-wide

interests looked to this structure as a way of eliminating the parochi-

alism and inefficiency of the traditional mayor-council form with its

ward-oriented councilmen and short-term executive.

Galveston adopted the plan in the aftermath of the disastrous 1900

flood when existing governmental machinery broke down. The com-

missioners, two of whom were elected by the voters of the city and

three appointed by the governor of the state, presided over the restora-

tion of the city and provided better services at lower taxes. Other east

Texas cities soon adopted the innovation. As in Galveston, leading

businessmen took the lead in getting charters changed and in serving

on the commissions. Des Moines, Iowa, went to the commission form

in 1907 and the idea was then publicized around the country as the

Des Moines Plan. With few exceptions, organized business and pro-

fessional groups supported the plan, while workers, ethnics, and so-

cialists opposed it. At-large elections, a key feature, raised the social

class level of government officials; workers and small businessmen did

not have the visibility or the resources to mount city-wide campaigns.

Moreover, the plan presupposed executive ability on the part of those

chosen. Often the initiative, referendum, and recall were added to the

commission form to enhance its appeal to believers in direct democ-

racy. However the usual requirement that the petitions calling for

such special elections be signed by one-fourth the number of voters

at the previous election limited the use of these devices.8

 

8. In a separately published article, Rice and Richard Bernard have examined the



Urban Political Change 319

Urban Political Change                                               319

 

Several serious weaknesses soon became apparent. Wichita, Kan-

sas, elected a popular street laborer as a commissioner and other cities

also chose men without the requisite executive talent or experience.

The combination of legislative and executive functions in the same

body violated the American tradition of separation of powers. The

commissioners did not always act as a body but rather tended to con-

centrate on their own departments. There was no central director or

authority to limit squabbling and ensure cooperation. The at-large

elections and the business domination of most commissions ignored

minority interests and social welfare measures. When the city man-

ager form emerged a few years later, Richard Childs of the Short Bal-

lot Association and the leaders of the National Municipal League

abandoned the commission form for the city manager which prom-

ised  the benefits without the weaknesses. In retrospect, for most

cities and most of its advocates, the commission plan served as a way

station between the traditional mayor-council form and the city

manager.

Rice's treatment of the rise and fall of the commission plan sup-

ports that offered by James Weinstein in the 1960s. What Weinstein

presented in outline, Rice has now offered in detail. He does suggest

that major newspapers and downtown business organizations were

not the only supporters of the proposal; in Fort Worth, organized

labor was brought into the coalition. So while Rice offers some shad-

ings to Weinstein's portrait, the essentials remain unchanged. Rice's

work is nonetheless useful for his careful examination of a number

of cities and the way in which he demonstrates the interaction be-

tween reformers with a national orientation such as Richard Childs

and local elites in bringing about the desired changes. He also has a

useful appendix listing all cities adopting the commission form and

the year in which the innovation was introduced.

Rice's emphasis on the role of businessmen in bringing about ur-

ban political change is supported by most of the essays in a collection

edited by Michael Ebner and Eugene Tobin, The Age of Urban Re-

form: New Perspectives on the Progressive Era. The volume con-

sists of ten essays by young scholars, most of which embody portions

 

statistical probabilities of cities choosing the commission or city manager form. Their

analysis indicates that cities most prone to adopt one of these charter forms were

moderate in size, newer, youthful in age composition with an ethnically homogeneous

old-stock population and relatively large numbers of white collar workers and home

owners. Of 156 cities studied, twenty-five fit the above profile but did not adopt either

form; in nineteen other cases, cities did change their charters without possessing all

of the expected characteristics. Richard M. Bernard and Bradley R. Rice, "Political

Environment and the Adoption of Progressive Municipal Reform," Journal of Urban

History, I (February 1975), 149-74.



320 OHIO HISTORY

320                                                OHIO HISTORY

 

of the authors' dissertation research. Each essay deals with only one

city; comparative studies are easier to talk about and to advocate than

to do. The cities treated range from east coast (Chelsea, Mass., New

York, Passaic and Jersey City, and Philadelphia) to west (Seattle

and Los Angeles), dip into the South with Atlanta and Houston, and

include Chicago as the middle western representative. As the editors

note in their introduction, the essays vary in the questions asked and

in the answers supplied. Since there is no comparability in subject or

methodology, the pieces must be considered as case studies of various

aspects of municipal government and politics in the early twentieth

century. In a general way, most of the authors support the thesis that

organized business and professional men played the major role in in-

stituting changes in governmental form and function during these

years, whether the particular subject be Houston's charter, Atlanta's

schools, or Seattle's Municipal League. The point is probably suffi-

ciently accepted by now that the authors do not have to treat it either

as revelation or conspiracy, which was often the dominant tone of his-

torians writing in the 1960s.

One of the most provocative essays in the book is Michael McCar-

thy's study of the impact of Chicago's physical expansion upon its

political life. The elites of various suburban towns successfully sought

annexation to Chicago in the 1880s. In the 1890s the Municipal Vot-

ers League came into being as a means of combining the interests and

influence of native American middle-class people. Presumably

there is some connection between these developments in that geo-

graphical dispersion required a city-wide organization, that people

scattered in various wards could not otherwise make their wishes felt.

Unfortunately McCarthy does not demonstrate the nature of the rela-

tionships between the events described. He also includes material on

the changing locations of ethnic groups within the city. One wishes

that the piece were considerably longer so that McCarthy would have

the opportunity to develop the points introduced. Despite this caveat,

the essay is still one of the most interesting in the book for its recogni-

tion of the importance of space and spatial relations in urban history.

In an equally provocative and too brief piece, Augustus Cerillo, Jr.,

provides a useful portrait of the relationship between ideology and

organizational development in New York City's government. In eigh-

teen pages he examines the impact of Lawrence Veiller on housing

reform, Herman Biggs on the health department, Charles Evans

Hughes on the Public Service Commission, William Allen, Henry

Bruere, and Frederick Cleveland on the privately supported Bureau

of Municipal Research, and the relationship between the bureau and

the mayoral administration of John Purroy Mitchel (1914-1917). Un-



Urban Political Change 321

Urban Political Change                                       321

 

like Schiesl, Cerillo concludes that Mitchel and his followers concen-

trated excessively on efficiency and economy and ignored human needs.

His essay is valuable for showing in a specific context the way in

which public administrators and independent reformers developed

their ideas on methods for greater governmental effectiveness and ex-

panded public responsibility and then put them into practice.

Using Los Angeles as his case study, Martin Schiesl also empha-

sizes the growing importance of professional administrators who to a

considerable extent replaced old style organization politicians as the

key power bloc in the city. Los Angeles progressives destroyed the

old machine through the adoption of nonpartisan, at-large elections,

and numerous recommendations of the extra-governmental Efficiency

Commission. These changes enhanced the power of administrators in

their drive to enlarge the scope of their activities and in their effort

to resist pressures for change from external sources. Schiesl con-

cludes that in Los Angeles the reformed bureaucracy was an en-

trenched power bloc by 1920. In the light of subsequent history, when

the enormous clout of organized municipal employees has become ap-

parent almost everywhere, the point is persuasive on its face, although

one would appreciate a few specific illustrations.

Some of the other essays also provide insights useful beyond the

immediate case study under consideration. For example, in his study

of Philadelphia housing, John Bauman offers a good treatment of

the conflict in values between reformers, whether motivated by scien-

tific or social concern, and the bulk of the population. The reformers

succeeded in getting legislation passed, but keeping it intact and

providing for effective enforcement was another matter. Lee Pren-

dergass treats Seattle politics in terms of a conflict between an older

elite and a new group of businessmen and professionals struggling for

power. As outs the new group presented themselves as reformers;

once in power they became increasingly conservative. Wayne Urban

concludes that school reform in Atlanta conforms to the business ori-

ented model advanced by David Tyack in his general history of urban

education. The book has eight tables which might be useful if they

could be read, but they cannot, at least by me. The five maps are

rather better. The editors also include a useful bibliographic essay.

Taken together, then, these four books, especially Schiesl's, add

to our knowledge and understanding of urban government and poli-

tics in the progressive era. They may be evidence of a new historio-

graphic phase in which scholars can equitably assess the strengths

and weaknesses of urban progressivism, and by extension the Ameri-

can political tradition, without feeling compelled to be ideologically

partisan attackers or defenders of that tradition.